Thư viện tri thức trực tuyến
Kho tài liệu với 50,000+ tài liệu học thuật
© 2023 Siêu thị PDF - Kho tài liệu học thuật hàng đầu Việt Nam

MONEY, MACROECONOMICS AND KEYNES phần 8 doc
Nội dung xem thử
Mô tả chi tiết
Second, the aggregate demand function is assumed to be less sensitive to the
interest rate than is aggregate supply, and hence the AD schedule cuts the AS from
above. The relative insensitivity of aggregate demand to interest rate changes was,
of course, a staple of the ‘Old Keynesian’ literature (and was implicit in the
Keynesian Cross). However, in that context it was not combined with a palpable
degree of interest sensitivity of supply, as is done here. For simplicity, the AD
schedule in Fig. 15.2 is shown as completely interest insensitive. However, clearly
nothing would be changed by allowing some interest elasticity, as long as this is
less than on the supply side.
The third important point is that in Fig. 15.2 the (real) rate of interest is taken
to be a financial variable determined essentially by the monetary policy of the
central bank. It is determined outside the aggregate demand and supply nexus
itself, and in the diagram shows up as a horizontal line across the page, at a predetermined level, . The underlying monetary theory is therefore that of the Post
Keynesian ‘horizontalist’ school, in which the interest rate (including the real
rate) is effectively a policy instrument, and the money supply is endogenous. This
is contrasted with Barro’s version in Fig. 15.1, in which there in no theory of
money and the interest rate is taken literally to be a real (non-monetary) variable.
Victoria Chick (e.g. 1984, 1986, 1991, 1995) has written extensively on Post
Keynesian monetary theory, endogenous money, the theory of banking and
alternative views on interest rate determination. She has indeed described horizontalism (e.g. that of Moore 1979)4 as an ‘extreme’ position (Chick 1986: 116),
while nonetheless making it clear that as a first approximation this is still a far
more reasonable assumption than the alternative (neoclassical) extreme. The main
objection to treating the interest rate as a purely policy-determined variable would
be the extent to which this neglects Keynes’s insights about liquidity preference
and the role of speculation in financial markets (Chick 1995: 31). The practical
implication would be that there can be occasions in which the monetary authorities may not get their way in setting the interest rate.5 Keynes himself had argued
this way in the General Theory (Keynes 1936: 202–4), although elsewhere (even
as late as 1945) he had stated that ‘The monetary authorities can have any interest rate they like … Historically … (they) … have always determined the rate at
their own sweet will …’ (as quoted by Moore 1988b: 128).
For our present purposes, however, the debate about the precise degree of control of interest rates by central bankers may perhaps be set on one side. There
would clearly be general agreement that the stance of monetary policy is at least
a major influence on the real interest rate. Moreover, from the perspective of the
principle of effective demand, the main point at issue is not exactly how the rate
is set, but rather that it is not taken to be determined by demand and supply in
barter capital markets, as in the neoclassical model, and is exogenous to the ‘real
economy’ in that sense.6
Note, however, that if we do proceed to take the interest rate as either an exogenous or directly policy-determined variable, the issue immediately arises as to
how demand and supply could ever come into equilibrium. In neoclassical or new
r
J. SMITHIN
154
classical theory, interest rate adjustment itself is supposed to be the equilibrating
mechanism, but that is ruled out in any horizontalist approach. However, it can be
suggested here that for the SOE an obvious equilibrating mechanism does exist,
namely changes in the real exchange rate. Or, it would be more accurate to say, a
combination of real exchange rate changes and output adjustment. This issue is
taken up below.
4. A simple aggregate demand and supply model for
the small open economy
Consider the following simple aggregate demand and supply ‘curves’ (they are
actually linear) for the SOE:
, (1)
. (2)
Equation (1) represents the aggregate demand schedule. The demand for output
depends positively on autonomous spending, A(t), as in traditional Keynesian
models, and positively on Q(t), where Q(t) is the real exchange rate. The nominal
rate is defined as the domestic currency price of one unit of foreign exchange, so
an increase in Q(t) represents a real depreciation. The argument is therefore that
a real depreciation increases the demand for net exports and hence total aggregate
demand. As discussed, for the sake of argument there is assumed to be no interest rate term in eqn (1), which is an extreme instance of the view that the demand
schedule is insensitive to interest rate changes.
Equation (2) is the aggregate supply schedule. This is assumed to be negatively
sloped, not positively sloped, for the reasons discussed above. Also, a real depreciation is taken to have a negative impact on supply. This arises as the result of
real wage resistance on the part of the labour force, and/or because of an increase
in the real costs of imported raw materials.
We can rearrange eqn (1) to yield
. (3)
Then use (3) in (2) and set aggregate demand equal to aggregate supply:
(4)
Now solve for Y(t):
{(1) (2)/[(2) (2)]}A(t) {(2) (1)/[(2) (2)]}r(t) (5)
Y(t) [(0) (2) (2) (0)]/[(2) (2)]
{[(1) (2)]/(2)}A(t).
Y(t) (0) (1)r(t) [ (2)/(2)]Y(t) [(0) (2)]/(2)
Q(t) Yd
(t)/(2) (0)/(2) [(1)/(2)]A(t)
Ys
(t) (0) (1)r(t) (2)Q(t)
Yd
(t) (0) (1)A(t) (2)Q(t)
AGGREGATE DEMAND
155