Thư viện tri thức trực tuyến
Kho tài liệu với 50,000+ tài liệu học thuật
© 2023 Siêu thị PDF - Kho tài liệu học thuật hàng đầu Việt Nam

MONEY, MACROECONOMICS AND KEYNES phần 3 potx
Nội dung xem thử
Mô tả chi tiết
wealth by their loans. To maintain this conviction, the State targets some rate
of growth of the banks’ own net wealth, which explains the origin of banks’
rather unchecked power to determine the effective rate of interest and the rate of
mark-up firms have to attain (Parguez 1996, 2000a). At the onset, banks and State
are intertwined. The power of banks is always a power bestowed on them by
the State. The State therefore must impose financial constraints if it wants to
maintain the value of money.
Since the State allows the banks’ debts to become money, it has the power to
create money at will for its own account to undertake its desired outlays. The
endorsement of bank debt means that it is convertible into State money. In the
modern economy, State creates money through the relationship between its banking department, the central bank, and its spending department, the treasury. State
money is created as deposits or debts are issued on itself by the central bank. State
money obviously has the same value than bank deposits because of the financial
constraints banks imposed on borrowers and therefore on employment, which
includes the rate of interest and the rate of mark-up. The power of banks to issue
debts on themselves is the outcome of evolution of debtor–creditor relationship
(Innes 1913). As soon as a society escapes from the despotic command stage, production is sustained by a set of debt relationships. Debts of the credit-worthiest
units begin to be accepted as means of settling debts resulting from acquisitions.
Soon there are units, which are so credit worthy that their debts are universally
accepted as means of acquisition, at least within a given space. When they specialize into the issue of debts on themselves, it is tantamount to deem them banks.
There is now a new major question: how could modern banks evolve out of a
complex debt structure, which is Victoria Chick’s ‘mystery’? Answering this
question is to explain how the banks’ own debts can be homogeneous by being
denominated in the ‘right’ units, in which real wealth is accounted. There are only
two alternatives: the first is the solution of Menger (1892), according to whom
the banks’ existence would spontaneously evolve out of a pure market process
without any State intervention; the second is to explain the banks’ existence by
the State intervention (Parguez and Seccareccia 2000).
The Mengerian alternative is irrelevant because it is tantamount to some
Walrasian tâtonnement. The second alternative imposes that money cannot
exist without the support of the State as the sole source of legitimacy. It is the
State which bestows on the banks’ debts the nature of money by allowing
banks to denominate in the legal universal unit, in which its own money is denominated. State money is universally accepted by sellers to the State and firms
because they are certain of the ability of the State to increase real wealth by its
expenditures.
Ultimately, all money can be deemed both ‘State money’ and ‘symbolic
money’. It is ‘State money’ either directly or indirectly because banks create
money by delegation of the State. It is ‘symbolic money’ because for all temporary holders it is the symbol of the access to the real wealth generated by initial
expenditures financed by the creation of money.
THEORY OF MONETARY CIRCUIT
47
3. Money is ephemeral but it is not insignificant
The creation of money is the outcome of two debt relationships:
R1: between banks and State on one side, and future debtors on the other side;
R2: between money recipients (acquisitors) and sellers.
Money is injected into the economy by R2 to allow the payment of the future debt
entailed by R1 when it will be due. Money is only created or exists to allow
debtors to pay their debts in the future. The payment of this debt therefore entails
the destruction of money, which proves that money is created because it will be
destroyed. The future debt is due when it can be paid out of proceeds or income
generated by initial expenditures undertaken through R2. In the case of firms, the
future debt is due when the sale of output has generated the receipts, which are
the proof of the effective creation of wealth initiated by the creation of money.
Assuming that proceeds are equal to the payable debt, all the money recouped by
firms is destroyed. In the case of the State, the future debt is due when the private
sector, or rather households as the ultimate bearers of the tax debt, has earned
its gross income out of initial money creation for both State and firms. Tax payments entail an equal destruction of money, which explains why the State cannot
accumulate money in the form of a surplus (Parguez 2000b).
Money exists only in the interval between initial expenditures and payment of
the future debt, which is their counterpart. Money cannot therefore be logically
accumulated. Contrary to the core assumptions of both neoclassical and Keynesian
economics, there cannot be a demand-for-money function because money cannot
be a reserve of wealth. Let us assume that some private sector units want to accumulate money over time to enjoy a liquid reserve of wealth. Money created
through R1/R2 only has a purchasing power on the real output generated by outlays
resulting from R2. As soon as production has been realized, money has lost its
value, it has no more use and must be destroyed. Hoarded money does not have
a value. If hoarders decide to spend it, hoarded money would crowd out newly
created money, and the outcome would be inflation leading to a rise in the rate of
mark-up above its targeted level. The so-called ‘reserve of value’ characteristic
contradicts the nature of money. It could only refer to some imaginary ‘commodity money’.
A desire for accumulating money is the mark of an anomaly that could jeopardize the stability of the economy. In any period, an increase in the desired stock
of hoarded money reflects a share of ex post saving which is itself a share of
income accruing to the private sector; it is just, according to the very accurate
definition of Lavoie (1992), a ‘residual of a residual’ that ought to be nil.
The existence of desired hoarding leads to two alternative models: either there
is no compensation and an unforeseen debt to banks is forced on firms, or the
thirst for hoarding is quenched by the increase in the stock of State money provided by the State deficit. Therefore, I can spell out the rigorous proof of a proposition of the neo-Chartalist school (Wray 1998): the minimum deficit the State
A. PARGUEZ
48