Thư viện tri thức trực tuyến
Kho tài liệu với 50,000+ tài liệu học thuật
© 2023 Siêu thị PDF - Kho tài liệu học thuật hàng đầu Việt Nam

Imperialism, Sovereignty and the Making of International Law Part 6 doc
Nội dung xem thử
Mô tả chi tiết
174 imperialism, sovereignty and international law
a colony, economic forces had a profound impact on native society that
hardly could be reversed by the actions of the colonial government, no
matter how solicitous and well intended. Social relations were transformed purely into economic relations, political authority became a
means by which the market could be furthered, and with the dissolution
of the traditional checks on behaviour ‘there remain[ed] no embodiment
of social will or representative of public welfare to control the economic
forces which the impact of the West release[d]’.231 Political advancement
and independence hardly became a reality in these circumstances.
It was not only the systems of governance that were dictated by economic goals. The old model of colonialism suggested that economic
progress was an end in itself and that welfare would be achieved by
progress. The new model suggested instead that active state intervention
was necessary to achieve welfare.232 Native welfare was a principal preoccupation of enlightened colonial administrators and the PMC. And yet, as
Lugard’s own comments suggest, such concerns were entirely utilitarian:
labour was an asset that had to be preserved.233 Given the decisive importance of economic development to the whole project of colonial governance, it followed that economic development almost inevitably distorted the policies intended to protect native welfare. Thus, as Furnivall
points out: ‘[T]he services intended to furnish the necessary protection
function[ed] mainly to make production more efficient, and the services
intended to promote welfare directly by improving health and education
[had] a similar result; though designed as instruments of human welfare
they [were] perverted into instruments of economic progress.’234
Economic development is crucial to the well being of any society. In
this situation, however, economic progress was equated with the furtherance of a system of economic inequalities specific to colonialism.
Analysing colonial economies in the period more generally, Abernethy
soberly concludes that colonial economies were export oriented and specialised in the production of a few commodities. Furthermore, the systematic integration of the colonial economy into the metropolitan economy on disadvantageous terms created even greater ties of dependency
and vulnerability in the colony.235 In addition, of course, the native
231 Ibid., p. 298. Furnivall’s detailed and lucid exposition of the effect of individualism
and market forces on traditional societies is all the more powerful for its notable lack
of sentimentality or nostalgia for vanishing village communities. Ibid., pp. 297--299. 232 See Furnivall, Colonial Policy, p. 288. 233 See the discussion above. 234 Furnivall, Colonial Policy, p. 410. 235 As Abernethy soberly states: ‘Because of such policies, the typical colony’s economic
prospects were unusually dependent on forces operating outside its boundaries and
beyond its control.’ Abernethy, The Dynamics, p. 114.
t h e m a n da t e s y s t e m o f t h e l e ag u e o f n a t i o n s 175
peoples hardly received the real value of the raw materials extracted
from their territories.236
But these were not the only reasons why economic development had a
devastating impact on native societies. Rather, the dominance of the economic, as discussed, profoundly altered the whole system of legitimacy,
of authority, and of the meaning that held mandate societies together.
The doctor and anthropologist W. H. R. Rivers, intent on identifying the
cause of the massive population declines in Melanesia that accompanied
the introduction of civilization to that region, argued that
[i]t may at first sight seem far-fetched to suppose that such a factor as loss of
interest in life could ever produce the dying out of a people, but my own observations have led me to the conclusion that its influence is so great that it can
hardly be overrated.237
My argument has been that the economic and social policies actively
endorsed by the PMC had profoundly damaging consequences for mandate peoples. It also must be noted, however, that in many instances,
the PMC was unable to check abuses of the system by the mandatory
powers themselves. Native cultures, as I have argued earlier, possessed
no inherent validity for the PMC, but the PMC did recognize the importance of at least getting some impression of native views and responses.
The Mandate System, however, failed to provide any formal mechanism
by which the native could communicate meaningfully with, and represent herself before, the PMC. In basic terms, the native was spoken
for by the mandatory power. Initially, Smuts argued for some native
236 See generally Woolf, Empire; Rodney, How Europe Underdeveloped Africa. The topic of the
economics of imperialism raises very complex questions. For a recent account see,
e.g., B. R. Tomlinson, ‘Economics and Empire: The Periphery and the Imperial
Economy’, in Andrew Porter (ed.), The Oxford History of the British Empire: The Nineteenth
Century (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999), pp. 53--75. But focusing on a specific
Mandate Territory, it was estimated that the three administering trustee powers
(Australia, New Zealand and the United Kingdom) made a profit of about 165 million
pounds from the exploitation of Nauru’s phosphates while Nauru was a mandate and
then a trust territory. For a detailed study of accounting issues relating to Nauru, see
Weeramantry, Nauru, chapters 13, 16. Some idea of the scale of exploitation is
suggested by the fact that in 1928, the people of Nauru received 2.6 per cent of the
value of their phosphates. Ibid. at p. 235. It is likely that studies of the economies of
other mandate territories such as Rwanda--Urundi would reveal similar, if not worse
levels of exploitation and profiteering by the mandate power. 237 W. H. R. Rivers, ‘The Psychological Factor’, in W. H. R. Rivers (ed.), Essays on the
Depopulation of Melanesia (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1922), pp. 84, 94.
Rivers’ work was discussed by the PMC. He is a central character in Pat Barker’s superb
Regeneration trilogy of novels -- Regeneration, The Eye in the Door and The Ghost Road.
176 imperialism, sovereignty and international law
representation, at least to the extent of consulting the natives as to
whether or not they were agreeable to the mandatory chosen. Only
the advanced mandates participated in this process. For the rest, Smuts
argued, consultation was simply inapplicable, on account of the backwardness of the peoples concerned.238 The PMC attempted to establish a
system by which petitions from the natives themselves could be received.
The subject of petitions was treated, however, as a delicate one, liable to
generate great tensions.239 The compromise formula, arrived at in 1923,
permitted the PMC to receive petitions from inhabitants of the mandate
territories, but only through the mandatory, which appended comments
prior to sending the petitions on to the Commission.240
The peoples of the mandate territories inevitably resisted the profound
changes being made to their societies and ways of life. The people of
Nauru, for instance, attempted in a number of different ways to prevent
the phosphate mining that was destroying their island. Tragically, however, given the various limitations of the petition system, the actions of
these peoples, at least at the international level, became largely what
they were represented to be by the mandatory powers.
The ironies are made clear by the 1922 Bondelzwart riots in SouthWest Africa, which -- certain members of the PMC observed with
the restraint of seasoned diplomats -- could be attributed to ‘native
grievances arising in part from legislative and administrative action in
behalf of the white settlers’.241
Political and procedural factors -- the PMC’s practice of giving the
mandatory large discretion when the issues involved were those relating
to security -- largely precluded PMC criticism of the measures adopted.242
Indeed, the Commission, as reported by Wright, partially commended
the South African response ‘“in taking prompt and effective steps to
uphold government authority and to prevent the spread of disaffection”, though because of the absence of native evidence no opinion could
be expressed, “whether these operations were conducted with needless
severity”.’243
Within this system, native discontent could express itself only as
rebellion, the meaning of which was interpreted and established by the
League. The PMC response to the rebellion, however, simply confirmed
238 See Smuts, ‘The League of Nations’, p. 28. 239 Wright, Mandates, pp. 169--178. 240 Ibid., p. 169. 241 Ibid., p. 209. 242 Ibid. 243 Wright, Mandates, p. 198 (citing the PMC’s statement from the Third Session).