Thư viện tri thức trực tuyến
Kho tài liệu với 50,000+ tài liệu học thuật
© 2023 Siêu thị PDF - Kho tài liệu học thuật hàng đầu Việt Nam

Understanding the Digital Economy pot
Nội dung xem thử
Mô tả chi tiết
Understanding the Digital Economy
This Page Intentionally Left Blank
Understanding the Digital Economy
Data, Tools, and Research
edited by Erik Brynjolfsson and Brian Kahin
The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, and London, England
© 2000 Massachusetts Institute of Technology
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced in any form by any
electronic or mechanical means (including photocopying, recording, or information
storage and retrieval) without permission in writing from the publisher.
This book was printed and bound in the United States of America.
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Understanding the digital economy : data, tools, and research / edited by Erik
Brynjolfsson and Brian Kahin.
p. cm.
Includes bibliographical references and index.
ISBN 0-262-02474-8 (hc : alk. paper)
1. Electronic commerce—Congresses. I. Brynjolfsson, Erik. II. Kahin, Brian.
HF5548.32 .U53 2000
330.9—dc21 00-033947
Contents
Introduction 1
Erik Brynjolfsson and Brian Kahin
The Macroeconomic Perspective
Measuring the Digital Economy 13
John Haltiwanger and Ron S. Jarmin
GDP and the Digital Economy: Keeping up with the
Changes 34
Brent R. Moulton
Understanding Digital Technology’s Evolution and
the Path of Measured Productivity Growth: Present
and Future in the Mirror of the Past 49
Paul A. David
Market Structure, Competition, and the Role of
Small Business
Understanding Digital Markets: Review and
Assessment 99
Michael D. Smith, Joseph Bailey, and Erik Brynjolfsson
Market Structure in the Network Age 137
Hal R. Varian
The Evolving Structure of Commercial Internet
Markets 151
Shane Greenstein
Small Companies in the Digital Economy 185
Sulin Ba, Andrew B. Whinston, and Han Zhang
vi
Contents
Small Business, Innovation, and Public Policy in
the Information Technology Industry 201
Josh Lerner
Employment, Workforce, and Access
Technological Change, Computerization, and the
Wage Structure 217
Lawrence F. Katz
The Growing Digital Divide: Implications for an
Open Research Agenda 245
Donna L. Hoffman and Thomas P. Novak
Extending Access to the Digital Economy to Rural
and Developing Regions 261
Heather E. Hudson
Organizational Change
IT and Organizational Change in Digital
Economies: A Sociotechnical Approach 295
Rob Kling and Roberta Lamb
Organizational Change and the Digital Economy:
A Computational Organization Science Perspective 325
Kathleen M. Carley
The Truth Is Not Out There: An Enacted View of
the “Digital Economy” 352
Wanda J. Orlikowski and C. Suzanne Iacono
Contributors 381
Index 389
Introduction
Erik Brynjolfsson and Brian Kahin
“The digital economy—defined by the changing characteristics of information, computing, and communications—is now the preeminent driver
of economic growth and social change. With a better understanding of
these fundamental transformations, we can make wiser decisions—whether
we are investing in research, products, or services, or are adapting our
laws and policies to the realities of a new age.”—Neal Lane, Assistant to
the President for Science and Technology, April 1999
Although there is now a substantial body of literature on the role
of information technology in the economy, much of it is inconclusive. The context is now changing as the success of the Internet and
electronic commerce (“e-commerce”) introduces new issues of
influence and measurement. Computers created a platform for the
commercial Internet; the Internet provided the platform for the
Web; the Web, in turn, provided an enabling platform for ecommerce. The Internet and the Web have also enabled profound
changes in the organization of firms and in processes within firms.
The Internet links information to locations, real and virtual. It
links the logic of numbers to the expressive power and authority of
words and images. Internet technology offers new forms for social
and economic enterprise, new versatility for business relationships
and partnerships, and new scope and efficiency for markets.
The commercial Internet has only had about six years to play out
in earnest, but the numbers show a remarkable acceleration—a
doubling of Internet connections year after year and, more recently, a variety of figures on e-commerce showing even faster
growth. Web transaction costs are as much as 50–99 percent less
2
Brynjolfsson and Kahin
than conventional transaction costs.1
It is this chain of drivers and
its implications for the economy and society as a whole that leads
us to speak of a digital economy.
The term “information economy” has come to mean the broad,
long-term trend toward the expansion of information- and knowledge-based assets and value relative to the tangible assets and
products associated with agriculture, mining, and manufacturing.
The term “digital economy” refers specifically to the recent and still
largely unrealized transformation of all sectors of the economy by
the computer-enabled digitization of information.
Because of its mandate in matters of interstate commerce and
foreign trade, the federal government has primary responsibility
for evaluating the health and direction of the economy. The
emerging digital economy makes commerce less local, more interstate, and, especially, more global, in line with a long-term trend
toward market liberalization and reduced trade barriers. At the
same time, the picture presented by public information sources is
becoming less and less complete. What we know about e-commerce
comes from proprietary sources that use inconsistent methodologies. Economic monitoring, like policy development, is challenged
by quickly evolving technologies and market practices.
The nature and scope of the digital economy are matters of
concern to nations at all levels of development. Like consistent
legal ground rules, an open, testable platform of public economic
information is essential to investment and business decisions. It is
also essential to sound monetary policy and to setting taxes and
spending budgets. Ultimately, understanding the digital economy
is relevant to a wide range of policies: R&D investment, intellectual
property, education, antitrust, government operations, accounting standards, trade, and so on.
All countries must confront the unfettered flow of information
on the Internet and the ease with which international transactions
and investments can take place. While the digital economy is
known as a generator of new business models and new wealth, it is
also undermining old business models and threatening investments and jobs in certain established businesses. With the excitement comes anxiety and concern about the how the ingredients of
the digital economy should be configured for optimal advantage.
Introduction
3
Outside the United States, it is sometimes viewed as a suspect
phenomenon, deriving in part from American strengths in computer technology and software, flat-rate phone service, and the
scale advantages of the English language. For all these reasons, it
begs investigation.
In April 1998, the U.S. Department of Commerce issued The
Emerging Digital Economy, a landmark report that recognized the
accelerating importance of the Internet and e-commerce in the
national economy. Bearing the imprimatur of the federal government, the report offered new perspective on the role of information technology in productivity, inflation, economic growth, and
capital investment. It has been cited frequently and succeeded by
a number of reports assessing these and other developments.2
In November 1998, as part of the second phase of an initiative on
global electronic commerce, President Clinton charged the assistant to the president for economic policy to undertake an assessment of the digital economy. In addition to asking the Department
of Commerce to update The Emerging Digital Economy, the president
asked that experts be convened to assess the implications of the
digital economy and to consider how it might best be measured and
evaluated in the future. Accordingly, an interagency working
group on the digital economy planned a public conference, which
took place on May 25–26, 1999, at the Department of Commerce
(www.digitaleconomy. gov). The conference was sponsored by the
Department of Commerce, the National Science Foundation, the
National Economic Council, the Office of Science and Technology
Policy, and the Electronic Commerce Working Group, the umbrella interagency group for the administration’s global e-commerce initiative.
The conference sought a common baseline for understanding
the digital economy and considered how a clearer and more useful
picture of that economy might be developed. While recognizing
the convergence of communications, computing, and information, the conference looked beyond those sectors to focus on the
transformation of business and commerce, processes and transactions, throughout the economy.
This book’s four parts mirror the four basic topics considered at
the conference:
4
Brynjolfsson and Kahin
• The macroeconomic perspective: How do we measure and assess “the
digital economy” and its implications for the economy as a whole?
• The texture of the digital economy: How do firms compete and how
do markets function, and how is this different from traditional
competition? What are the opportunities for and impediments to
the participation of individuals and small businesses?
• The impacts on labor demand and participation: Do the new technologies exacerbate inequality? What skills, technologies, and
institutions are needed to support broader access to the benefits of
the digital economy by different individuals and groups?
• Organizational change: How does the digital environment affect
the structure and operation of firms and institutions?
The Macroeconomic Perspective
Information technology is playing an increasing role in growth,
capital investment, and other aspects of the economy. The scope
and significance of these transformations remain open to question,
however, in large part because underlying measurement and methodology problems have not been resolved.
• How should we identify and measure the key drivers of the digital
economy?
• What are the industry-level and economy-wide investments related to e-commerce, including investments in information technology equipment and workers?
• What are the implications for growth, employment, productivity,
and inflation?
• How should we account for intangible consumer benefits and
burdens?
There are three chapters in this part. In “Measuring the Digital
Economy,” John Haltiwanger and Ron Jarmin note that the emergence of e-commerce is part of a broad spectrum of changes over
several decades related to advances in information technology and
the growth of the broader digital economy. After reviewing the
current activities of federal statistical agencies, they conclude that
current data collection activities are inadequate and provide some
Introduction
5
practical advice on how to improve measurement of the digital
economy.
In “GDP and the Digital Economy: Keeping up with the Changes,”
Brent Moulton argues that inadequate measurement of the true
output of the digital economy has contributed to past difficulties
economists have had in identifying the productivity benefits of the
IT revolution. He shows that despite these measurement difficulties, the measured contribution of computers to GDP has grown
substantially in the late 1990s, and he outlines an agenda for
improving research in this area.
In a seminal paper a decade ago, Paul David noted that new
technologies such as electric motors or computers require enormous complementary investments, such as changes in organizational structure, in order to reach their full productive potential.3
In his chapter, “Understanding Digital Technology’s Evolution
and the Path of Measured Productivity Growth: Present and Future
in the Mirror of the Past,” David provides a detailed review of the
subsequent literature and shows how much of the micro and macro
evidence on IT and productivity affirms the importance of organizational complements.
Market Structure, Competition, and the Role of Small Business
The digital economy includes information and communications
technology, e-commerce, and digitally delivered services, software,
and information. The characteristics of these goods and services
(including factors such as economies of scale, network effects,
public good characteristics, and transaction costs) can lead to
different market structures and competitive conditions. Unfortunately, such characteristics are difficult to measure, technologies
are changing rapidly, and relevant market boundaries are fluid and
difficult to define. Some have speculated that the Internet and ecommerce hold great promise for small firms, by liberating them
from proprietary value chains, diminishing transaction costs, and
providing access to global markets, but without adequate data it is
difficult to test this speculation.
• What are the relationships and interactions between the economic characteristics of digital technologies, products, and ser-
6
Brynjolfsson and Kahin
vices and the structure and competitiveness of markets?
• What are the key determinants of prices (overall price levels,
price flexibility, price dispersion, etc.), market structure and efficiency (competitive, noncompetitive, segmented, etc.), and competition (price based, market share based, etc.)?
• What roles do startups and small firms play in different segments
of the digital economy? What are the barriers to launching and
growing small firms?
• How and to what extent do the Internet and e-commerce either
benefit or handicap entrepreneurs and small- to medium-sized firms?
The five chapters in this part review the empirical evidence on
how competition and strategy differ in the digital economy. Two of
the chapters specifically look at the changing role of smaller firms.
In “Understanding Digital Markets: Review and Assessment,”
Michael Smith, Joseph Bailey, and Erik Brynjolfsson summarize the
recent literature on how the Internet is affecting competition and
market efficiency. They start with findings for several dimensions
of market efficiency and then focus on the puzzling finding of
unusually high price dispersion on the Internet. They conclude
with a set of developments to watch and provide an annotated
appendix of research on the Internet and competition.
In “Market Structure in the Network Age,” Hal Varian shows how
several fundamental principles of economics can be used to increase understanding of how e-commerce changes competition.
He analyzes versioning, loyalty programs, and promotions, in each
case illustrating his points with examples from e-commerce and
outlining the research issues raised.
Shane Greenstein admirably demonstrates the value of developing new data sources in his chapter, “The Evolving Structure of
Commercial Internet Markets.” He focuses on the commercialization of a key link in the e-commerce value chain: the Internet
Service Providers (ISPs) who supply access to the Internet for
millions of consumers and businesses. Using this example, he
analyzes a set of broader questions that are important for researchers, policymakers and managers.
In “Small Companies in the Digital Economy,” Sulin Ba, Andrew
Whinston, and Han Zhang outline some of the Internet’s special
Introduction
7
opportunities and challenges for smaller enterprises. They focus
on the way information asymmetries on the Internet enhance the
importance of branding and of trusted third parties, and they
describe some significant technologies that are likely to help with
these issues.
In “Small Business, Innovation, and Public Policy in the Information Technology Industry,” Josh Lerner documents the ambiguous
overall role of small business in innovation but shows that a
particular subset of small businesses—firms that are venture
backed—have been particularly strong innovators. He focuses on
the concentration of venture financing in IT industries and concludes by discussing recent changes in intellectual property laws
that appear to favor larger firms, drawing some implications for
policy makers.
Employment, Workforce, and Access
As information and communications technologies transform the
global economy, they are changing the U.S. workforce in terms of
size, composition, and the knowledge and skills required for
success. Indeed, the competitiveness of nations and companies
appears increasingly dependent on the ability to develop, recruit,
and retain technologically sophisticated workers. There are concerns that the U.S. workforce is already unable to meet the market
demand for skilled and knowledgeable workers and that this gap is
growing. Furthermore, there is growing concern that the benefits
of the digital economy are not equitably shared, giving rise to a
“digital divide.” There are a variety of options for overcoming
barriers to participation, and it is important to understand the
extent to which such options are available, utilized, and costeffective.
• How reliable are current models for projecting the size and
composition of labor markets in occupations where technologies
are changing rapidly? How can they be improved?
• How does the growth of e-commerce and investment in the
Internet and related technologies affect the level and composition
of labor market demand? How can these influences be untangled
from other factors?
8
Brynjolfsson and Kahin
• What can be learned from firm-level or industry-level studies as
compared to aggregate labor market models?
• What barriers impede the diffusion of e-commerce across the
society?
• To what extent and in what ways does e-commerce enhance,
preserve, or diminish diversity? To what extent does e-commerce
work to increase or lessen opportunities for economic progress for
disadvantaged individuals, groups, and regions?
The three chapters in this part raise troubling questions about
growing inequality and underscore that the benefits of the digital
economy are not necessarily evenly spread among different groups
in society.
In “Technological Change, Computerization, and the Wage
Structure,” Larry Katz discusses one of the most troubling economic phenomena of the past two decades. Wage inequality has
expanded dramatically, making the rich even richer relative to the
poor. Katz notes that this widening inequality has coincided with
growing use of IT and is particularly closely linked to increased
relative demand for more educated and skilled workers. He reviews
the existing literature and suggests some new empirical approaches
that might help us identify the relationships among computerization, demand for skilled labor, and income inequality.
Donna Hoffman and Thomas Novak summarize a range of
statistical evidence in “The Growing Digital Divide: Implications
for an Open Research Agenda.” They highlight the differential
levels of computer adoption and Internet usage among various
demographic groups. The provocative facts they review raise important questions for researchers and policy makers who are
concerned about the potential gap between information “haves”
and “have-nots.”
In “Extending Access to the Digital Economy to Rural and
Developing Regions,” Heather Hudson examines opportunities
for extending Internet access to disadvantaged groups in industrial
nations and also to populations in developing nations. She documents some striking disparities in basic measures of access, such as
telephone lines, and provides a useful guide to future research in
this area as well as an appendix summarizing some of the available
technological options.