Thư viện tri thức trực tuyến
Kho tài liệu với 50,000+ tài liệu học thuật
© 2023 Siêu thị PDF - Kho tài liệu học thuật hàng đầu Việt Nam

The Rise and Fall of Abacus Banking in Japan and China phần 3 potx
Nội dung xem thử
Mô tả chi tiết
Chapter 2
The Rise of
Abacus Banking in Japan
In the summer of 1997, in the middle of the banking crisis, one of the
authors tried to wire money to the United States through a major bank
in Japan. To his dismay, the employee-crowded branch could not handle
the wire transfer and he had to visit another downtown branch, not to
mention that he had a hard time finding someone who could speak English. But even when he arrived at the other branch, things were no better.
He received several greetings, a box of tissues, and free blood pressure
monitoring services, but not the ‘‘core’’ banking services he expected. In
fact, it was easier for the Foreign Exchange desk manager at the bank to
recommend a ‘‘competing’’ bank rather than undergo the procedure of
wire transferring. In the end, after waiting for over an hour and after
checking his blood pressure several times in the monitor across the bank
counter, the desk manager did him a ‘‘favor.’’ He went to an ATM machine to withdraw the cash, counted the money three times—one with
his abacus, another with an electronic calculator, and a third in his PC—
and wired it to the United States, for a hefty triple fee: a currency conversion fee, a wire transfer fee, and the loss of ten days’ interest (the
time it took the bank to have the funds transferred).
Though just a personal experience, this example demonstrates how
Japanese banks treat their clients, and how such treatment differs from
that offered by banks in other countries, especially the United States.
Specifically, in the United States, a visit to the local branch of a major
20 The Rise and Fall of Abacus Banking in Japan and China
bank and a moderate fee are sufficient for wiring money overnight, all
over the world. But the difference between Japanese and U.S. and European banking extends beyond money-wiring procedures and fees to the
ways that Japanese banking performs its fundamental functions and
earns its income, and the ways that government bureaucrats supervise
the industry and control the behavior of bank managers.
In the United States, private banks are true for-profit institutions. According to prevailing corporate governance, individual and institutional
stockholders who appoint professional managers to oversee the day-today operations own them. In this sense, managers are accountable to the
bank stockholders. They must enhance stockholder value or risk losing
their positions.1 At the same time, bank managers must limit traditional
risks (liquidity and credit risks), market risks (foreign currency risk, interest rate risk, liquidation risk, etc.), and operational risks. Government
regulators impose a number of constraints to limit competition in the
banking industry and the risks associated with it. The Glass-Steagall Act,
for instance, limits cross-state competition and competition between the
banking and securities industries. Yet government regulators do not
monitor the day-to-day operations of individual banks and control the
behavior of bank managers. This has been especially true since the late
to mid-1970s, when currency liberalization, financial deregulation, and
globalization weakened the Glass-Steagall Act and increased both market
opportunities and risks. In this sense, U.S. bank managers perform a dual
function—as accountants, monitoring fund flows in and out of the bank
treasury, and as credit risk analysts, evaluating the risk and returns of
investment alternatives.
In contrast to American banks, Japanese private banks are not true forprofit institutions. According to the prevailing corporate governance,
bank stockholders appoint management to oversee day-to-day operations, but have little control over it.2 Specifically, banks that are owned
by large corporations and operate under what is known as keiretsu relations are not too concerned with profits, but rather with relations and
mutual obligations with other keiretsu members. In this form of ‘‘relational banking,’’ banks serve more as corporate welfare agencies, providing low-cost financing to their keiretsu clients who are also their
shareholders as compared to other clients, rather than as true, profitmaximizing enterprises. Japanese banks are not overly concerned with
traditional banking risks either. Under a policy known as ‘‘overlending,’’
for instance, the BOJ has virtually eliminated liquidity risk.
Keiretsu relations, fast economic growth, and rising asset prices have