Thư viện tri thức trực tuyến
Kho tài liệu với 50,000+ tài liệu học thuật
© 2023 Siêu thị PDF - Kho tài liệu học thuật hàng đầu Việt Nam

The Enterprise of Law
Nội dung xem thử
Mô tả chi tiết
The
Enterprise
of Law
Justice Without the State
Bruce L. Benson
Copyright © 2011 The Independent Institute Previously published © 1990 by the Pacific Research Institute
for Public Policy Cover Design: Roland de Beque Cover Image: © Gary S. Chapman / Getty Images All
rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced or transmitted in any form by electronic or
mechanical means now known or to be invented, including photocopying, recording, or information storage
and retrieval systems, without permission in writing from the publisher, except by a reviewer who may
quote brief passages in a review. Nothing herein should be construed as necessarily reflecting the views of
the Institute or as an attempt to aid or hinder the passage of any bill before Congress.
The Independent Institute
100 Swan Way, Oakland, CA 94621-1428
Telephone: 510-632-1366 · Fax: 510-568-6040
Email: [email protected]
Website: www.independent.org
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data available
ISBN: 978-1-59813-069-0
15 14 13 12 11 5 4 3 2 1
CONTENTS
Preface: The Enterprise of Law after Twenty Years
Acknowledgments
1 Introduction
Part I From Voluntary to Authoritarian Law
2 Customary Legal Systems with Voluntary Enforcement
3 The Rise of Authoritarian Law
Part II A Public Choice Approach to Authoritarian Law
4 Law and Justice as a Political Market
5 The Demand Side of the Political Market
6 The Supply Side of the Political Market
7 Corruption of Law Enforcement Officials
Part III Reemergence of Private Alternatives
8 Contracting Out for Law and Justice
9 Current Trends in Privatization
10 Benefits of Privatization
Appendix to Chapter 10
Part IV Rationalizing Authoritarian Law
11 Market Failure in Law and Justice
12 The Legal Monopoly on Coercion
Appendix to Chapter 12
Part V From Authoritarian to Private Law
13 Political Barriers to Privatization
14 Envisioning a Private System
Index
About the Author
Praise for The Enterprise of Law
About the Independent Institute
Independent Studies in Political Economy
PREFACE
THE ENTERPRISE OF LAW AFTER TWENTY
YEARS
This is being written on the twentieth anniversary of the first publication of The
Enterprise of Law: Justice Without the State (hereafter, Enterprise). Much has
happened over these two decades. I have continued to engage in research on
justice without the state and on government failure in the provision of law. As a
consequence, my own understanding of these issues has evolved. Furthermore,
while very few legal and economic scholars considered the idea of justice
without the state to be a legitimate research issue in 1990, this is no longer the
case. In fact, the academic literature on topics discussed in Enterprise has
expanded dramatically.
1 Much of this literature corroborates various conclusions
from the book,
2 but there are also growing numbers of critics who apparently
recognize that their command theory of law and their efforts to justify statemade law are facing serious challenges.
3 As usual, however, the most important
developments have been outside academia.
People’s disgust with many public legal institutions is greater today than it
was in 1990. The reasons for government failure in law are the same as they
were two decades ago, as little has been done to change the fundamental
institutionalized incentives facing government decision-makers detailed in
Enterprise. Voters cannot seem to decide which political party they like the
least, so they put one party in power for a few years, get fed up with its
performance, and put the other party in power. Similar disgust with the public
courts can be seen in the ubiquitous legislative battles over tort reform4 and the
political backlash against decisions like Kelo v. City of New London (545 U.S.
469 (2005)).
5 Dissatisfaction with public policing services grows with each new
procedure imposed in airports by the Transportation Safety Administration and
the never-ending stories of police shootings of unarmed civilians. Political
corruption is so prevalent that it has become an expected part of the process in
states like New York, New Jersey, and Louisiana, not to mention Washington,
DC.
As government failure in the provision of law and justice has continued, the
private sector has responded with innovation in and growth of non-state
alternatives for government creation of and changes in rules, enforcement of
these rules, and adjudication of disputes. Consider Table 9.3, for instance, as it
reports growth in the number of firms offering detective and protection services
in the United States, and number of employees of those firms from 1964 to
1981.
6 The number of firms increased by 285 percent over this period from 1988
to 7126, while the number of employees rose from 62,170 to 331,294, a 423
percent increase. The following Table provides a sampling of these same annual
counts in the 1990s and into the new century, comparing them to both 1964 and
1981.
Clearly the private security industry has continued to grow at a tremendous
rate. The same is true for private dispute resolution services. While a few
examples of arbitration for disputes between firms and their consumers were
noted in Chapter 9, for instance, today it is difficult to find a contract between
firms and consumers that does not have an arbitration clause in it. An entirely
new arena for the private development of rules and enforcement mechanisms has
developed with the emergence of markets on the Internet,
7 but similar
developments also are occurring in emerging markets in Eastern Europe and
Asia.
8
In the process of my ongoing research, I have found weaknesses and/or gaps
in some of my original arguments that I now know can be strengthened and
filled. Other shortcomings that can also be dealt with or have already been
addressed,
9 have been pointed out by critics. None of these problems change the
primary conclusions expressed in the book. In fact, by addressing the problems, I
have solidified my views about the potential benefits of private provision of
justice and the inevitable failure of state legal systems to provide justice. The
only part of Enterprise that I wish I had written differently is the concluding
chapter’s predictions about what a system of justice without the state might look
like. I noted that many predictions about the technology, institutions, processes,
and organizations that might arise are likely to be very inaccurate, but I am now
even more convinced that unshackling the private sector creates such strong
incentives for entrepreneurial discovery that no one can predict the resulting
technological, institutional, and organizational innovations. One need only read
predictions about today’s technology, institutions, and organizations made a few
decades ago by very intelligent and imaginative people to see that this is correct.
Nobel Laureate in Economics, Paul Samuelson, obviously a much more
intelligent person than I am, so misunderstood the market discovery process that
in the 1973 edition of his famous textbook Economics he predicted that the
Soviet Union, which supposedly had a per capita income equal to about 50
percent of the United States’ at the time, should catch up by 1990, and clearly
this would occur by 2015. In the 1989 13th edition of Economics he stated that,
“The Soviet economy is proof that . . . a socialist command economy can
function and even thrive.”
10 The Soviet economy and the command economies in
Eastern Europe that were styled after it collapsed over the next two years. I am
not suggesting that the general predictions of the chapter and Enterprise as a
whole are wrong: private provision of law would be both more efficient and
more just. I am simply saying that what such a legal system might actually look
like is beyond my powers to imagine, so I expect that the picture I drew in 1990
is likely to be much too simplistic.
ENDNOTES
1. For a few of many examples, see Lisa Bernstein, “Opting Out of the Legal System: Extralegal
Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry,” Journal of Legal Studies, 21 (1992), 115–158;
Avner Greif, “Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade,” American
Economic Review, 83 (1993), 525–548; Avner Grief, Institutions and the Path to the Modern
Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade (New York, Cambridge University Press, 2006); Robert C.
Ellickson, Order Without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes (Cambridge, MA, 1991); Robert C.
Ellickson, “Property in Land,” Yale Law Journal, 102 (1993): 1315–400; Peter Leeson, “An-arrghchy: The Law and Economics of Pirate Organization,” Journal of Political Economy, 115 (2007),
1049–1094; Paul Milgrom, Douglas North, and Barry Weingast, “The Role of Institutions in the
Revival of Trade: the Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs,” Economics and
Politics 2 (1990), 1–23; D. Johnson and D. Post, “Surveying Law and Borders—Law And Borders
—The Rise of Law in Cyberspace,” Stanford Law Review, 48 (1996), 1367–1402; Matt Ridley, The
Origins of Virtue: Human Instincts and the Evolution of Cooperation (New York, 1996); Andrew
Morriss, “Miners, Vigilantes & Cattlemen: Overcoming Free Rider Problems in the Private
Provision of Law,” Land and Water Law Review 33 (1998), 581–696; Andrew Morriss, “Private
Actors and Structural Balance: Militia and the Free Rider Problem in Private Provision of Law,”
Montana Law Review 58 (1997), 115–166; Todd Zywicki, “The Rise and Fall of Efficiency in the
Common Law: A Supply-Side Analysis,” Northwestern Law Review, 97 (2003), 1551–1634; Randy
E. Barnett, The Structure of Liberty: Justice and the Rule of Law (Oxford, UK: Oxford University
Press, 1998); “Daniel B. Klein, ed. Reputation: Studies in the Voluntary Elicitation of Good
Behavior (Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, 1997); Terry L. Anderson and P. J. Hill,
The Not so Wild, Wild West: Property Rights on the Frontier (Stanford University Press, 2004); and
Edward Stringham, ed. Anarchy and the Law (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction for The
Independent Institute, 2007).
2. Examples include O. Volckart and A. Mangels, “Are the Roots of the Modern Lex Mercatoria
Really Medieval?” Southern Economic Journal, 65 (1999), 427–450; C. Fassberg, “The Empirical
and Theoretical Underpinnings of the Law Merchant: Lex Mercatoria—Hoist with Its Own Petard?”
University of Chicago Journal of International Law, 5 (2004), 67–82; E. Kadens, “The Empirical
and Theoretical Underpinnings of the Law Merchant: Order within Law, Variety within Custom:
The Character of the Medieval Merchant Law,” University of Chicago Journal of International Law,
5 (2004), 39–65; C. Donahue, Jr., “The Empirical and Theoretical Underpinnings of the Law
Merchant: Medieval and Early Modern Lex mercatoria: An Attempt at the probatio diabolica,”
University of Chicago Journal of International Law, 5 (2004), 21–37; C. Drahozal, “Competing and
Complementary Rule Systems: Civil Procedure and ADR: Contracting out of National Law: an
Empirical Look at the New Law Merchant,” Notre Dame Law Review, 80 (2005), 523–552; C.
Drahozal, “Busting Arbitration Myths,” Kansas Law Review, 56 (2008), 663–677; and S. Sachs,
“From St. Ives to Cyberspace: The Modern Distortions of the Medieval Law Merchant,” American
University International Law Review, 21 (2006), 685–812. These and other criticisms are being
rebutted in Bruce L. Benson, “Yes Virginia, there is a Law Merchant,” a partially completed book
manuscript, Department of Economics, Florida State University.
3. Bruce L. Benson, “Uncertainty, the Race for Property Rights, and Rent Dissipation due to Judicial
Changes in Product Liability Tort Law,” Cultural Dynamics, 8 (November 1996), 333–351.
4. For detailed discussion see various chapters in Bruce L. Benson (ed.), Property Rights: Eminent
Domain and Regulatory Takings Re-Examined (Palgrave/Macmillan for The Independent Institute,
2010).
5. These data were collected from the annual County Business Patterns reports from the Bureau of the
Census.
6. Note that these figures do not include security employment working directly for non-security firms
like banks, malls, casinos and other recreational firms like nightclubs and Disney World, and so on.
Total employment of private security personnel is substantially higher. A recent newspaper article
contends that there are more than a million contract security officers and another million or more
private security guards in the U.S. compared to about 700,000 public police (Amy Goldstein, “More
security firms getting police powers: Some see benefits to public safety, but others are wary,” San
Francisco Chronicle, January 7, 2007) [most recently viewed, December 19, 2010, at
http://www.sfgate.com/cgi-bin/article.cgi?file=/c/a/2007/01/07/MNGVENCASV1.DTL].
7. Bruce L. Benson, “The Spontaneous Evolution of Cyber Law: Norms, Property Rights, Contracting,
Dispute Resolution, and Enforcement without State Involvement,” Journal of Law, Economics and
Policy, 1(Winter 2005), 269–348.
8. Bruce L. Benson, “It Takes Two Invisible Hands to Make a Market: Lex Mercatoria (Law
Merchant) Always Emerges to Facilitate Emerging Markets,” Studies in Emergent Order, Spring
2010, Vol. 3, 100–128.
9. See notes 2 and 8, for example, as well as David W. Rasmussen and Bruce L. Benson, The
Economic Anatomy of a Drug War: Criminal Justice in the Commons (Lanham, MD: Rowman and
Littlefield, 1994); Bruce L. Benson, To Serve and Protect: Privatization and Community in
Criminal Justice (New York: New York University Press for The Independent Institute, 1998), and
numerous other publications listed at http://garnet.acns.fsu.edu/~bbenson/.
10. Paul Samuelson and William Nordhaus, Economics, 13th ed. (McGraw Hill, 1989), 837. For
discussion of other erroneous predictions by Samuelson and references to sources dealing with
similar issues, see Alan Ebenstein, “The Poverty of Samuelson’s Economics,” Liberty 17:4 (April
2003), 37–38, http://freedomkeys.com/samuelson.htm last viewed December 18, 2010.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
This project has taken several years to complete, and a large number of people
have either been significantly affected by it or had significant effects on it. I
would like to acknowledge as many of them as I can recall. First, I must thank
my wife Terrie and daughter Lacey for their ongoing support. They put up with
me as I tried to juggle an over-committed research agenda that ate up many of
the weekends and evenings I should have spent with them. The secretaries at
Montana State University and Florida State University typed several very
different drafts of the book, transferred various drafts from one word processing
system to another twice, and finally, one of them taught me to do my own word
processing. But some of the secretaries also got interested in what I was writing
and began to comment on it and ask questions about it. Three deserve special
thanks in this regard: Anne Phillips, Vickie Garland, and Carol Bullock.
Over the course of its evolution, this manuscript benefited greatly from a
number of reviews. In particular, Randy Barnett reviewed the first draft of the
book, and from the perspective of a legal scholar, he recommended much of the
literature on legal theory and history that I have since drawn on extensively.
Furthermore, from the perspective of a former prosecuting attorney, Professor
Barnett corrected numerous misperceptions I had about the criminal justice
process. Finally his extensive comments and organizational suggestions were
invaluable.
Several other reviewers were also very helpful in guiding this book’s
development, including Terry Anderson, Gordon Tullock, Marshall Fritz, Harold
Berman, and C. S. Cockbum. Terry Anderson, in his capacity as the Pacific
Research Institute’s economic advisor, was particularly instrumental in
determining the book’s final form and content. With his help and advice, and
with Marianne Keddington’s editing of the final draft, the book was made
considerably more readable (and much shorter). Other people affiliated with the
Pacific Research Institute provided me with useful comments and reference
material, including Chip Mellor, Charles Baird, David Theroux, and Greg
Christainsen. In addition, correspondence and conversations with Leonard
Liggio (and several other people affiliated with the Institute for Humane
Studies), Murray Rothbard, Lawrence Sherman, and Chuck Logan led me to
explore useful references that I probably would have missed. Encouraging
comments by P. J. Hill and others (again including Gordon Tullock and Charles
Baird) on a chapter I wrote for a Pacific Research Institute book (“Guns for
Protection and Other Private Sector Responses to the Fear of Violent Crime,” in
Firearms and Violence: Issues of Regulation, Don Kates, Jr., ed. [Cambridge,
Mass.: Ballinger Press, 1984]) actually led to my further investigation of the
issues examined in this book. Many discussions with colleagues at Montana
State and Florida State, such as Ron Johnson, Merle Faminow, Terry Anderson,
Rick Stroup, Dick Wagner, Larry Wollen, Tom McCaleb, Randy Holcombe,
Dave Rasmussen, and others I apologize for forgetting to mention, also helped
me formulate and sharpen my arguments. Parts of the book were presented at the
Legal Studies Workshop and the Political Economy Seminar Series at Florida
State University, as well as the Public Choice Seminar Series at George Mason
University, the Austrian Economics Colloquium at New York University, the
Public Choice Society meetings, and the Southern Economic Association
meetings. Discussion following those presentations was very beneficial. The
Liberty Fund also sponsored a conference organized by the Pacific Research
Institute on “Law, Liberty, and Responsible Individuals” in June of 1989. That
conference provided me with an opportunity to subject part of my work to
critical evaluation by a gathering of eminent legal and economic scholars.
Indeed, much of the book has undergone considerable indirect peer review.
Certain sections draw on earlier publications of mine in the Journal of
Libertarian Studies, the Antitrust Bulletin, the Southern Economic Journal, the
Journal of Legal Studies (written with John Baden), the Pacific Research
Institute sponsored book Firearms and Violence: Issues of Regulation, edited by
Don Kates, Jr., and in a chapter (written with M. L. Greenhut) for Antitrust and
Regulation, edited by Ronald Grieson (Lexington Books, 1986). In addition,
materials developed and written for this book have already been published in the
Madison Papers Series, the Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy, the
Journal of Libertarian Studies, the International Review of Law and Economics,
the Cato Journal, the Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, and
the Southern Economic Journal. I thank all of these book publishers and
journals, their editors and referees, and my coauthors for their contributions. The
Southern Economic Journal’s choice of my paper drawn from this book (“The
Spontaneous Evolution of Commercial Law”) to receive the Georgescu-Roegen
Prize as the best article published in the journal during 1988-1989 is a
particularly pleasing recognition by my peers that my work on this subject might
be worthy of attention.
Several institutions must also be acknowledged. My departments and
department chairmen at both Montana State and Florida State were always very
supportive. The Institute for Humane Studies provided financial support in the
form of an F. Leroy Hill Summer Fellowship, that allowed me to explore a
number of related issues much more deeply than I might have, and much of the
work they supported ultimately found its way into the book. The Political
Economy Research Center also supported the development of several papers that
I have drawn upon for the book. Finally, and most significantly, I wish to
explicitly acknowledge the vital contributions made by people affiliated with the
Pacific Research Institute. I have already mentioned the valuable reviews and
comments on the book from Institute associates, but their contributions go far
beyond that. To start with, the Institute’s willingness to fund the book was what
convinced me that it was a project worth pursuing. The Institute’s continued
support of the project over what turned out to be a much longer period than
anyone anticipated has involved many people. In particular: Chip Mellor’s
behind the scenes efforts to keep the project on track, and to provide the kind of
technical and intellectual inputs I needed, were clearly essential (he also
proposed, organized, and ran the Liberty Fund Conference mentioned above);
Terry Anderson saw to it that the book was written and packaged in a fashion
that would maximize its chances of being marketable (subject to the constraints
arising from the limited abilities of the author); Pam Riley prepared the market
to receive the book; and Linda Clumeck prepared the book for the market. I am
sure that I am unaware of the full extent and importance of the efforts made by
these individuals and others at the Institute. Thank you all for your invaluable
contributions.
Bruce L. Benson
Department of Economics, Florida State University
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS UPDATE
What goes around comes around. I initiated the project that led to this book at
the urging of David Theroux who was President of the Pacific Research Institute
at the time. In fact, the contract to publish the book was actually signed by
David. David had moved on before publication, but he remained very supportive
throughout the process and since then. This reprinting also was instigated by
David, however, as it was due to his urging that I continued to ask the Pacific
Research Institute to turn the copyright over to me when they were no longer
interested in producing the book. With advice and assistance from Roy M.
Carlisle and David, I was finally able to obtain the copyright, and we
immediately began discussing a reprint.
In addition to David, Roy, and the Independent Institute, other individuals and
organizations also must be acknowledged and thanked for their efforts to keep
The Enterprise of Law alive and circulating. The book never was heavily
advertised, but recognition and readership have grown fairly steadily for years,
largely through word of mouth. Leonard Liggio has always been one of my
strongest supporters and an advocate for the book, even using it in law school
classes. Moreover, the Institute for Humane Studies has done more over the
years to advertise and distribute the book than any other organization. They gave
copies of the book to hundreds of students going through their summer
programs, and information about the book spread from there. More recently, the
Ludwig von Mises Institute has been a primary market source for the book. They
purchased a large number of copies from the last printing done by the Pacific
Research Institute and have been advertising it and offering it for sale at a very
reasonable price on their web page since then.
Many friends around the country have also generously recommended the book
and/or cited it favorably, including Edward Stringham, Benjamin Powell, Peter
Boettke, Peter Leeson, P. J. Hill, Alberto Benegas Lynch, and Nicholas Dykes,
as well as several people at Francisco Marroquin University, George Mason
University and the University of Aix-en-Provence, José Igncio del Catillo and
Jesús Gomez who translated the book into Spanish, and others who deserve to be
named. Thanks to all of you, named and unnamed.