Thư viện tri thức trực tuyến
Kho tài liệu với 50,000+ tài liệu học thuật
© 2023 Siêu thị PDF - Kho tài liệu học thuật hàng đầu Việt Nam

Tài liệu MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS IN BANKING AND FINANCE PART 2 pdf
Nội dung xem thử
Mô tả chi tiết
60
3
Why Financial Services Mergers?
The first chapter of this book considered how reconfiguration of the financial services sector fits into the process of financial intermediation
within national economies and the global economy. The chapter also explored the static and dynamic efficiency attributes that tend to determine
which channels of financial intermediation gain or lose market share over
time. Financial firms must try to “go with the flow” and position themselves in the intermediation channels that clients are likely to be using in
the future, not necessarily those they have used in the past. This usually
requires strategic repositioning and restructuring, and one of the tools
available for this purpose is M&A activity. The second chapter described
the structure of that M&A activity both within and between the four major
pillars of the financial sector (commercial banking, securities, insurance,
and asset management), as well as domestically and cross-border. The
conclusion was that, at least so far, there is no evidence of strategic dominance of multifunctional financial conglomerates over more narrowly
focused firms and specialists, or vice versa, as the structural outcome of
this process.
So why all the mergers in the financial services sector? As in many
other industries, various environmental developments have made existing institutional configurations obsolete in terms of financial firms’ competitiveness, growth prospects, and prospective returns to shareholders.
We have suggested that regulatory and public policy changes that allow
firms broader access to clients, functional lines of activity, or geographic
markets may trigger corporate actions in the form of M&A deals. Similarly, technological changes that alter the characteristics of financial services or their distribution are clearly a major factor. So are clients, who
often alter their views on the relative value of specific financial services
or distribution interfaces with vendors and their willingness to deal with
multiple vendors. And the evolution and structure of financial markets
Why Financial Services Mergers? 61
make it necessary to adopt broader and sometimes global execution capabilities, as well as the capability of booking larger transactions for
individual corporate or institutional clients.
WHAT DOES THE THEORY SAY?
Almost a half-century ago, Miller and Modigliani (1961) pioneered the
study of the value of mergers, concluding that the value to an acquirer of
taking over an on-going concern could be expressed as the present value
of the target’s earnings and the discounted growth opportunities the target offers. As long as the expected rate of return on those growth opportunities is greater than the cost of capital, the merged entity creates value
and the merger should be considered. Conversely, when the expected rate
of return on the growth opportunities is less than the cost of capital, the
merged entity destroys value and the merger should not take place.
To earn the above-market rate of return required for mergers to be
successful, the combined entity must create new cash flows and thereby
enhance the combined value of the merger partners. The cash flows could
come from saving direct and indirect costs or from increasing revenues.
Key characteristics of mergers such as inter-industry versus intra-industry
mergers and in-market versus market-extending mergers need to be examined in each case.
Put another way, from the perspective of the shareholder, M&A transactions must contribute to maximizing the franchise value of the combined firm as a going concern. This means maximizing the risk-adjusted
present value of expected net future returns. In simple terms, this means
maximizing the following total return function:
n E(R ) E(C ) t t NPVf t t0 (1 i α ) t t
where E(Rt
) represents the expected future revenues of the firm, E(Ct
)
represents expected future operating costs including charges to earnings
for restructurings, loss provisions, and taxes. The net expected returns in
the numerator then must be discounted to the present by using a risk-free
rate it and a composite risk adjustment αt
, which captures the variance of
expected net future returns resulting from credit risk, market risk, operational risk, reputation risk, and so forth.
In an M&A context, the key questions involve how a transaction is
likely to affect each of these variables:
• Expected top-line gains represented as increases in E(Ft
) due to
market-extension, increased market share, wider profit margins,
successful cross-selling, and so forth.
• Expected bottom-line gains related to lower costs due to economies
of scale or improved operating efficiency, usually reflected in improved cost-to-income ratios.
62 Mergers and Acquisitions in Banking and Finance
Figure 3-1A. Strategic
Positioning.
• Expected reductions in risk associated with improved risk management or diversification of the firm across business streams,
client segment, or geographies whose revenue contributions are
imperfectly correlated and therefore reduce the composite αt
.
Each of these factors has to be carefully considered in any M&A transaction and their combined impact has to be calibrated against the acquisition price and any potential dilutive effects on shareholders of the acquiring firm. In short, a transaction has to be accretive to shareholders of
both firms. If it is not, it is at best a transfer of wealth from the shareholders
of one firm to the shareholders of the other.
MARKET EXTENSION
The classic motivation for M&A transactions in the financial services
sector is market extension. A firm wants to expand geographically into
markets in which it has traditionally been absent or weak. Or it wants to
broaden its product range because it sees attractive opportunities that
may be complementary to what it is already doing. Or it wants to broaden
client coverage, for similar reasons. Any of these moves is open to build
or buy alternatives as a matter of tactical execution. Buying may in many
cases be considered faster, more effective, or cheaper than building. Done
successfully, such growth through acquisition should be reflected in both
the top and bottom lines in terms of the acquiring firm’s P&L account
and reflected in both market share and profitability.
Figure 3-1A is a graphic depiction of the market for financial services
as a matrix of clients, products, and geographies (Walter 1988). Financial
institutions clearly will want to allocate available financial, human, and
technological resources to those identifiable cells in Figure 3-1A that
promise to throw off the highest risk-adjusted returns. In order to do this,
they will have to appropriately attribute costs, returns, and risks to specific
cells in the matrix. But beyond this, the economics of supplying financial
Why Financial Services Mergers? 63
Figure 3-1B. Client-Specific
Cost Economies of Scope, Revenue Economies of Scope, and
Risk Mitigation.
Figure 3-1C. Activity-Specific
Economies of Scale and Risk
Mitigation.
services often depend on linkages between the cells in a way that maximizes what practitioners and analysts commonly call synergies.
Client-driven linkages such as those depicted in Figure 3-1B exist when
a financial institution serving a particular client or client group can supply
financial services—either to the same client or to another client in the
same group—more efficiently. Risk mitigation results from spreading exposures across clients, along with greater earnings stability to the extent
that earnings streams from different clients or client segments are not
perfectly correlated.
Product-driven linkages depicted in Figure 3-1C exist when an institution can supply a particular financial service in a more competitive
manner because it is already producing the same or a similar financial
service in a different client dimension. Here again there is risk mitigation
to the extent that net revenue streams derived from different products are
not perfectly correlated.
Geographic linkages represented in Figure 3-1D are important when
an institution can service a particular client or supply a particular service
more efficiently in one geography as a result of having an active presence
64 Mergers and Acquisitions in Banking and Finance
Figure 3-1D. Client, Product,
and Arena-Specific Scale and
Scope Economies, and Risk
Mitigation.
in another geography. Once again, the risk profile of the firm may be
improved to the extent that business is spread across different currencies,
macroeconomic and interest-rate environments, and so on.
Even without the complexities of mergers and acquisitions, it is often
difficult for major financial services firms to accurately forecast the value
to shareholders of initiatives to extend markets. To do so, firms need to
understand the competitive dynamics of specific markets (the various cells
in Figure 3-1) that are added by market extension—or the costs, including
acquisition and integration costs. Especially challenging is the task of
optimizing the linkages between the cells to maximize potential joint cost
and revenue economies, as discussed below.
ECONOMIES OF SCALE
Whether economies of scale exist in financial services has been at the heart
of strategic and regulatory discussions about optimum firm size in the
financial services industry. Does increased size, however measured, by
itself serve to increase shareholder value? And can increased average size
of firms create a more efficient financial sector?
In an information- and distribution-intensive industry with high fixed
costs such as financial services, there should be ample potential for scale
economies. However, the potential for diseconomies of scale attributable
to disproportionate increases in administrative overhead, management of
complexity, agency problems, and other cost factors could also occur in
very large financial firms. If economies of scale prevail, increased size will
help create shareholder value and systemic financial efficiency. If diseconomies prevail, both will be destroyed.
Scale economies should be directly observable in cost functions of financial services suppliers and in aggregate performance measures. Many
studies of economies of scale have been undertaken in the banking, insurance, and securities industries over the years—see Saunders and Cornett (2002) for a survey.
Why Financial Services Mergers? 65
Unfortunately, studies of both scale and scope economies in financial
services are unusually problematic. The nature of the empirical tests used,
the form of the cost functions, the existence of unique optimum output
levels, and the optimizing behavior of financial firms all present difficulties. Limited availability and conformity of data create serious empirical
problems. And the conclusion of any study that has detected (or failed to
detect) economies of scale or scope in a sample selection of financial
institutions does not necessarily have general applicability. Nevertheless,
the impact on the operating economics (production functions) of financial
firms is so important—and so often used to justify mergers, acquisitions,
and other strategic initiatives—that available empirical evidence is central
to the whole argument.
Estimated cost functions form the basis of most empirical tests, virtually all of which have found that economies of scale are achieved with
increases in size among small banks (below $100 million in asset size). A
few studies have shown that scale economies may also exist in banks
falling into the $100 million to $5 billion range. There is very little evidence
so far of scale economies in the case of banks larger than $5 billion. More
recently, there is some scattered evidence of scale-related cost gains of up
to 20% for banks up to $25 billion in size (Berger and Mester 1997). But
according to a survey of all empirical studies of economies of scale
through 1998, there was no evidence of such economies among very large
banks (Berger, Demsetz, and Strahan 1998). The consensus seems to be
that scale economies and diseconomies generally do not result in more
than about 5% difference in unit costs.
The inability to find major economies of scale among large financial
services firms also pertains to insurance companies (Cummins and Zi
1998) and broker-dealers (Goldberg, Hanweck, Keenan, and Young 1991).
Lang and Wetzel (1998) even found diseconomies of scale in both banking
and securities services among German universal banks.
Except the very smallest banks and non-bank financial firms, scale
economies seem likely to have relatively little bearing on competitive
performance. This is particularly true since smaller institutions are often
linked together in cooperatives or other structures that allow harvesting
available economies of scale centrally, or are specialists not particularly
sensitive to the kinds of cost differences usually associated with economies
of scale in the financial services industry. Megamergers are unlikely to
contribute—whatever their other merits may be—very much in terms of
scale economies unless the fabled “economies of superscale” associated
with financial behemoths turn out to exist. These economies, like the
abominable snowman, so far have never been observed in nature.
A basic problem may be that most studies focus entirely on firmwide
scale economies. The really important scale issues are likely to be encountered at the level of individual financial services. There is ample evidence,
for example, that economies of scale are both significant and important
for operating economies and competitive performance in areas such as