Thư viện tri thức trực tuyến
Kho tài liệu với 50,000+ tài liệu học thuật
© 2023 Siêu thị PDF - Kho tài liệu học thuật hàng đầu Việt Nam

Energy and the Wealth of Nations; An Introduction to Biophysical Economics
Nội dung xem thử
Mô tả chi tiết
Energy and the
Wealth of Nations
Charles A.S. Hall
Kent Klitgaard
An Introduction to Biophysical Economics
Second Edition
Energy and the Wealth of Nations
Charles A.S. Hall
Kent Klitgaard
Energy and the
Wealth of Nations
An Introduction to Biophysical Economics
Second Edition
Charles A.S. Hall
College of Environmental Science & Forestry
State University of New York
Syracuse, New York, USA
Kent Klitgaard
Wells College
Aurora, New York, USA
ISBN 978-3-319-66217-6 ISBN 978-3-319-66219-0 (eBook)
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-66219-0
Library of Congress Control Number: 2018935116
© Springer International Publishing AG 2012, 2018
This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of
the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar
methodology now known or hereafter developed.
The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt from the
relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use.
The publisher, the authors and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in this
book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publisher nor the
authors or the editors give a warranty, express or implied, with respect to the material contained herein
or for any errors or omissions that may have been made. The publisher remains neutral with regard to
jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Printed on acid-free paper
This Springer imprint is published by Springer Nature
The registered company is Springer International Publishing AG
The registered company address is: Gewerbestrasse 11, 6330 Cham, Switzerland
To Myrna, my wonderful companion on this and other journeys.
Charles A.S. Hall
To my children, Justin and Juliana Klitgaard Ellis, who have grown from wonderful
children into fine adults, and to Deborah York who continues to make me a better
person.
Kent A. Klitgaard
Preface
There are four books on our shelf that have
the words, more or less, “wealth of nations”
in their titles. They are Adam Smith’s 1776
pioneering work, An Inquiry into the
Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations,
and three of recent vintage, David Landes’
The Wealth and Poverty of Nations, David
Warsh’s Knowledge and the Wealth of
Nations, and Eric Beinhocker’s The Origin
of Wealth. Warsh’s book is rather supportive of current approaches to economics
while Beinhocker’s is critical, but all of
these titles attempt to explain, in various
ways, the origin of wealth and propose
how it might be increased. Curiously, none
have the word “energy” or “oil” in their
glossary (one trivial exception), and none
even have the words “natural resources.”
Adam Smith might be excused given that,
in 1776, there was essentially no science
developed about what energy was or how
it affected other things. In an age when
some 80 million barrels of oil are used
daily on a global basis, however, and when
any time the price of oil goes up a recession follows, how can someone write a
book about economics without mentioning energy? How can economists ignore
what might be the most important issue in
economics? In a 1982 letter to Science
magazine, Nobel Prize economist Wassily
Leontief asked, “How long will researchers
working in adjoining fields ... abstain from
expressing serious concern about the
splendid isolation within which academic
economics now finds itself?” We think
Leontief ’s question points to the heart of
the matter. Economics, as a discipline, lives
in a contrived world of its own, one connected only tangentially to what occurs in
real economic systems. This book is a
response to Leontief ’s question and builds
a completely different, and we think much
more defensible, approach to economics.
For the past 130 years or so, economics has
been treated as a social science in which
economies are modeled as a circular flow
of income between producers and consumers where the most important questions pertain to consumer choice. In this
“perpetual motion” of interactions
between firms that produce and households that consume, little or no accounting
is given of the necessity for the flow of
energy and materials from the environment and back again. In the standard economic model, energy and matter are
ignored or, at best, completely subsumed
under the term “land,” or more recently
“capital,” without any explicit treatment
other than, occasionally, their price. In
reality economics is about stuff, and the
supplying of services, all of which are very
much of the biophysical world, the world
best understood from the perspective of
natural, not social, sciences. But, within
the discipline of economics, economic
activity is seemingly exempt from the need
for energy and matter to make economies
happen, as well as the second law of thermodynamics.
Instead we hear of “substitutes” and “technological innovation,” as if there were
indefinite substitutes for matter, energy,
and the environment. As we enter the second half of the age of oil, and as energy
supplies and the social, political, and environmental impacts of energy production
and consumption become increasingly the
major issues on the world stage, this
exemption appears illusory at best. All
forms of economic production and
exchange involve the transformation of
materials, which in turn requires energy.
When students are exposed to this simple
truth, they ask why are economics and
energy still studied and taught separately?
Indeed, why is economics construed and
taught only as a social science, since in
reality economies are as much, and perhaps even principally, about the transformation and movement of all manner of
biophysical stuff in a world governed by
physical laws?
VII
Part of the answer lies in the recent era of
cheap and seemingly limitless fossil energy
which has allowed a large proportion of
humans to basically ignore the biophysical
world. Without significant energy or other
resource constraints, economists have
believed the rate-determining step in any
economic transaction to be the choice of
insatiable humans attempting to get maximum psychological satisfaction from the
money at their disposal, and markets
seemed to have an infinite capacity to
serve these needs and wants. Indeed the
abundance of cheap energy has allowed
essentially any economic theory to “work”
and economic growth to be a way of life.
For the last century, all we had to do was to
pump more and more oil out of the ground.
However, as we enter a new era of “the end
of cheap oil,” in the words of geologists and
peak oil theorists Colin Campbell and Jean
Laherrere, energy has become a game
changer for economics and anyone trying
to balance a budget.
In brief, this book:
5 Provides a fresh perspective on economics for those wondering “what’s
next” after the crash of 2008 and the
near cessation of economic growth for
much of the Western world since then
5 Summarizes the most important information needed to understand energy
and our potential energy futures
In summary, this is an economics text like
no other, and it introduces ideas that are
extremely powerful and are likely to transform how you look at economics and your
own life.
Charles Hall
Polson, MT, USA
Kent Klitgaard
Aurora, NY, USA
July 2017
Preface
Acknowledgments
We thank the Santa Barbara Family
Foundation, Roger C. Baker Jr., the UK
Department for International Development, the Endeavor Foundation, and several anonymous donors for financial
support; Steven Bartell, Garvin Boyle, and
Jim Gray for excellent editing of words and
ideas; Michelle Arnold for assistance in
getting the first edition together; Rebecca
Chambers, Ana Diaz, Michael Sciotti and
Heather Hiltbrand for their able assistance
with the data analysis, editing, and graphics for the first edition, and to Tyler Lewis,
Sarah Halstead, and Bellina Mushala for
assistance with the second edition; and our
students over the years for helping us think
about these issues. We thank the late, fantastic Howard Odum, who taught us about
systems thinking and the importance of
energy in everything, and John Hardesty
and Norris Clement, who introduced Kent
to the limits to economic growth. We
thank our colleagues economists Lisi Krall
and John Gowdy for providing valuable
advice and critique for this and other projects. Their continued collaboration makes
our work stronger. We also thank David
Packer, Executive Editor at Springer, for
believing in us and Myrna Hall and
Deborah York for the loving support and
infinite patience. We owe a special debt of
appreciation to Tina Evans, who provided
excellent and valuable suggestions for
revising the first edition into what we
believe is a much stronger and clearer
second edition.
IX
Contents
I Economies and Economics
1 How We Do Economics Today ................................................................................................... 5
2 How We Got to Where We Are Today: A Brief History of Economic
Thought and Its Paradoxes ........................................................................................................ 23
3 Problems with How We Do Economics Today ................................................................... 67
4 Biophysical Economics: The Material Basis ........................................................................ 81
5 Biophysical Economics: The Economics Perspective .................................................... 101
II Energy and Wealth: An Historical Perspective
6 The Evolution of Humans and Their Economies ............................................................. 123
7 Energy, Wealth, and the American Dream ......................................................................... 151
8 The Petroleum Revolution and the First Half of the Age of Oil ............................... 183
III Energy, Economics, and the Structure of Society
9 The Petroleum Revolution II: Concentrated Power
and Concentrated Industries .................................................................................................... 211
10 Twentieth Century: Growth and the Hydrocarbon Economy ................................... 227
11 Globalization, Development, and Energy .......................................................................... 259
12 Are There Limits to Growth? Examining the Evidence ................................................. 277
13 The Petroleum Revolution III: What About Technology? ............................................ 289
IV Energy and Economics: The Scientific Basics
14 What Is Energy and How Is It Related to Wealth Production? .................................. 299
15 The Basic Science Needed to Understand the Relation
of Energy to Economics ............................................................................................................... 323
16 The Required Quantitative Skills ............................................................................................ 361
17 Is Economics a Science? Social or Biophysical? ............................................................... 377
X
V The Science Behind How Real Economies Really Work
18 Energy Return on Investment .................................................................................................. 387
19 Peak Oil, EROI, Investments, and Our Financial Future ............................................... 405
20 The Role of Models for Good and Evil .................................................................................. 425
21 Applying a Biophysical Economics Approach to Developing Countries............. 439
VI Understanding How Real-World Economies Work
22 Peak Oil, Secular Stagnation, and the Quest for Sustainability .............................. 459
23 Fossil Fuels, Planetary Boundaries, and the Earth System ........................................ 475
24 Is Living the Good Life Possible in a Lower EROI Future? ........................................... 487
Supplementary Information
Index ...................................................................................................................................................... 507
Contents
XI
Authors’ Biographies
Charles Hall
is a systems ecologist who received his PhD under Howard
T. Odum at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill.
Charles Hall is the author or editor of 14 books and 300 articles. He is best known for his development of the concept of
EROI, or energy return on investment, which is an examination of how organisms, including humans, invest energy into
obtaining additional energy to improve biotic or social fitness. He has applied these approaches to fish migrations,
carbon balance, tropical land use change, and the extraction
of petroleum and other fuels in both natural and humandominated ecosystems. Presently he is developing a new
field, biophysical economics, as a supplement or alternative
to conventional neoclassical economics, while applying systems and EROI thinking to a broad series of resource and economic issues.
Kent Klitgaard
is professor of economics and the past Patti McGill Peterson
professor of social sciences at Wells College in Aurora,
New York, where he has taught since 1991. Kent received his
bachelor’s degree at San Diego State University and his master’s degree and PhD at the University of New Hampshire. At
Wells, he teaches a diverse array of courses including the History of Economic Thought, Political Economy, Ecological Economics, The Economics of Energy, Technology and the Labor
Process, and Microeconomic Theory and is a cofounder of the
Environmental Studies Program. Kent is active in the International Society for Ecological Economics and is a founding
member of the International Society for BioPhysical Economics. Recently, his interests have turned toward the degrowth
movement, and he has published multiple papers on the subject for Research and Degrowth. He has two children and is
interested in the outdoors in general: from hiking to beach
walking to the occasional round of golf (despite the high
energy use of golf courses). Kent is a Californian who still surfs
the frigid waters of New England when he gets a chance.
1 I
Economies and
Economics
Economies exist independently of how we study them.
Consequently, there may be significant differences between how
an actual economy operates and how we study it. In this section,
we will assess how we perceived and taught economics at
various times. We begin with the dominance perspective of
today, neoclassical economics, in chapter one. In the second
chapter, we examine various perspectives from the history of
economic analysis from the 18th to the 20th centuries, focusing
on the diverse theoretical viewpoints from the past, most of
which have little to do with the dominant view of the present.
7 Chapter 3 examines the present approach more closely from
the perspective of how well that view is related to actual economies. It frequently finds the present view severely wanting,
particularly in that it pays little attention to, and indeed is often
inconsistent with, the biological and physical world upon which
it is necessarily based. 7 Chapter 4 introduces a new, different,
way in which we can examine economies, one that is in fact
based on a proper biophysical underpinning. This approach is
called biophysical economics. We emphasize the critical importance of energy here. 7 Chapter 5 adds a social perspective that
is part of, and consistent with, the essential biophysical framework of this innovative approach.
In general, the entire discipline of economics has paid only a very
little attention to energy even though energy was, and remains,
the basis of economic activity and growth. Rather economics has
treated energy as it treats any other material resource: as a
commodity, useful but ultimately substitutable by other commodities. Historically, economists focused their efforts upon
capital and labor, and, occasionally, land as the driving economic
forces. However, energy issues lay not far beneath the surface of
economic reality and many economic concepts. Before the era of
classical political economy, English manufacturers had learned to
substitute coal for increasingly scarce charcoal to provide heat for
their processes. In 1784, James Watt patented a steam engine that could provide rotary
motion. The coal-driven industrial revolution was soon to follow. Economies had a new
characteristic: growth. Economists now think of growth as a normal characteristic of
economies, but this is only a relatively recent phenomenon, and it is highly linked to
increasing energy supplies, something that was not characteristic before about 1800.
This book is written by an ecologist and an economist, and part of our objective is to
assess where insights and principles from these two disciplines can be combined to
understand economies and nature, and their interactions, better. While the two disciplines may appear very different, we believe instead that the phenomena they study
are very similar in many ways. From a biological perspective, the economies of cities,
regions, and nations can be viewed as ecosystems, with their own structures and
functions, their own flows of materials and of energy, and with diversity and stability.
Human-dominated systems can exhibit many of the characteristics of natural systems.
At the same time, ecology is often referred to as “the economy of nature.” There are
similarities and differences between organisms in nature and people in modern economies: lions eat gazelles and gazelles eat grasses, trout subsist on insects, and plants
exploit nutrients in soils and space in which to intercept sunlight. Individuals and
groups find themselves in a relentless struggle to increase their energy gains and
decrease energy costs, for their ability to pass on its genes is possible only if it has
managed to acquire a large net energy balance. This is also true for humans, but
humans are different in that we consciously order the labor process and produce for
surplus, rather than for immediate use alone. Producing for surplus dates to the
Neolithic transition from hunting and gathering to settled agriculture.
When first encountering the words “biophysical economics,” most readers probably
asked, “what do those words mean?” The answer is deceptively simple: The word
“biophysical” refers to the material world, that which is usually, but not completely,
covered by courses in physics, chemistry, geology, biology, hydrology, meteorology,
and so on. This can be compared with a “social” or “anthropocentric” (i.e., humancentered) perspective that characterizes modern economics. In this second perspective, which is dominant in our society, humans believe that they can make any world,
or set of decisions, or economic systems that they wish – if they can just get the
policies right and enough time has passed for new technologies to come on line. The
subsequent world becomes our new reality and truth.
But we must ask: How do the powerful, governing physical laws, which we are all
prepared to accept in physics, chemistry, and biology classes, operate outside of the
scientist’s laboratory and the “natural” world? Scientists often think of these laws as
imposing constraints on a system. Do these constraints really disappear when human
ingenuity is applied to economics and markets? Most economics textbooks would lead
you to this conclusion, as growth is just a matter of human actions, technologies,
policies, and a healthy dose of ambition. Western culture and its leading commentators (with a few exceptions such as Joseph Tainter and Jared Diamond) do tend to
elevate personal and social aspects of a problem, specifically, human actors and their
ideas, above any biophysical considerations. Thus, we learn about history as the action
of great leaders; wars, if not always battles, are usually won or lost due to the biophysical resources that generals can bring to bear. Napoleon once quipped that “God fights
on the side with the best artillery.” There is little debate that the South had the better
generals in the Civil War, but the North had the industrial might. The North won
because of biophysical, not leadership, issues.
Most readers would not argue with the idea that we live in a world that is completely
beholden to the basic laws and principles of science. These basic laws include Newton’s laws of motion, the laws of thermodynamics, the law of the conservation of
matter, the best first principle, the principles of evolution, and the fact that natural
ecosystems tend to make soil and clean water while human-modulated systems tend
to destroy both. Do economic systems operate outside of these laws? Did the seemingly unconstrained technological and economic expansion of the twentieth century
show that these laws were irrelevant or at least insignificant when applied to economics and the satisfaction of human needs and wants?
There is no more important question as we attempt to move beyond the recent
financial trauma of the “Great Recession” and the enduring “secular stagnation.” Unfortunately, the biophysical laws, particularly as applied to energy, are not understood or
appreciated by most people, including most economists. Ironically, our focus on
exploiting and investing energy in the economic process has divorced many people
from the very biophysical realities that are necessary to sustain them. This includes our
ways of building dwellings, living in cites, importing food, being transported and
entertained, and so on while isolating our energy using activities in areas generally
isolated from people’s daily lives. In this book, we examine these issues through an
integrated view of economics that emphasizes scientific principles and a more frequent use of the scientific method. Together these chapters provide the beginnings of
a powerful new way to think about economics.
3 I
Contents
Chapter 1 How We Do Economics Today – 5
Chapter 2 How We Got to Where We Are Today: A Brief History
of Economic Thought and Its Paradoxes – 23
Chapter 3 Problems with How We Do Economics Today – 67
Chapter 4 Biophysical Economics: The Material Basis – 81
Chapter 5 Biophysical Economic: The Economic Perspective – 101