Thư viện tri thức trực tuyến
Kho tài liệu với 50,000+ tài liệu học thuật
© 2023 Siêu thị PDF - Kho tài liệu học thuật hàng đầu Việt Nam

An Outline of the history of economic thought
Nội dung xem thử
Mô tả chi tiết
AN OUTLINE OF THE HISTORY OF
ECONOMIC THOUGHT
This page intentionally left blank
An Outline of the
History of Economic
Thought
Second Edition Revised
and Expanded
ERNESTO SCREPANTI
and
STEFANO ZAMAGNI
Translated by David Field and Lynn Kirby
AC
Great Clarendon Street, Oxford OX2 6DP
AC
Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford.
It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship,
and education by publishing worldwide in
Oxford New York
Auckland Cape Town Dar es Salaam Hong Kong Karachi
Kuala Lumpur Madrid Melbourne Mexico City Nairobi
New Delhi Shanghai Taipei Toronto
With offices in
Argentina Austria Brazil Chile Czech Republic France Greece
Guatemala Hungary Italy Japan Poland Portugal Singapore
South Korea Switzerland Thailand Turkey Ukraine Vietnam
Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University Press
in the UK and in certain other countries
Published in the United States
by Oxford University Press Inc., New York
# Ernesto Screpanti and Stefano Zamagni, 2005
The moral rights of the authors have been asserted
Database right Oxford University Press (maker)
First published 2005
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced,
stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means,
without the prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press,
or as expressly permitted by law, or under terms agreed with the appropriate
reprographics rights organization. Enquiries concerning reproduction
outside the scope of the above should be sent to the Rights Department,
Oxford University Press, at the address above
You must not circulate this book in any other binding or cover
and you must impose the same condition on any acquirer
British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data
Data available
Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data
Data available
Typeset by Newgen Imaging Systems (P) Ltd., Chennai, India
Printed in Great Britain
on acid-free paper by
Biddles Ltd., King’s Lynn, Norfolk
ISBN 0–19–927913–6 (Hbk) 978–0–19–927913–5
ISBN 0–19–927914–4 (Pbk) 978–0–19–927914–2
1 3 5 7 9 10 8 6 4 2
PREFACE TO THE SECOND ENGLISH
EDITION
Our satisfaction in writing the second English edition of this book is easy to
imagine: not only are we assured of the utility of our work, but also have the
opportunity to enlarge and revise it. We have attempted to do this in various
ways. We have removed oversights and errors; we have made a few additions
and expanded a little on all chapters; we have re-written and simplified
various parts which students had found obscure or difficult to understand;
lastly, we have updated the bibliography, with the aim of offering useful
suggestions for further reading.
More substantial integrations have been made to chapters 1, 2, 4, 9 and 11.
In the first chapter we felt it necessary to recall the role played by humanism
and the Renaissance in the birth of political economy and, in particular, the
contribution they made to the formation of ‘civil humanism’, a philosophical
approach that fell into disuse following the advent of utilitarianism, but now
appears set for a second revival. In the chapter on Smith we have integrated
our exposition of the interpretations of his thought by recalling the one that
is today considered the most convincing, that of Smith as an institutionalist
economist. The chapter on Marx has also been enlarged to recall his concept
of man and his investigation into the social and institutional conditions of
capitalist production, two of the most topical parts of his thinking. Lastly,
in chapter 9, we have separated treatment of the post-Keynesian approach
from the so-called ‘new Keynesian macroeconomics’, by further expanding
on both and pointing out the important differences that distinguish the two
schools. We have also added a summary paragraph with a simple diagram
comparing the views of the various contemporary schools of macroeconomics.
In chapter 11 we have added extensive paragraphs on evolutionary games and
the theories of growth and complexity.
In addition, we have introduced a new chapter—the twelfth—which
deals with the current situation of economic science. The state of crisis
which has beset our discipline over the last thirty years appears even more
evident today than when we wrote the first edition of this book. Now we
believe it to be a healthy crisis and in chapter 12 we have endeavoured to
explain why. A crisis can also be a revolution. We do not pretend to know
what will happen in economic science over the next twenty years or so, but
it seemed important to us to clarify the reason why, in our opinion, we are
in the middle of a crisis of foundations that may make history begin again
from Adam.
Finally, a formal change has been made which we hope will be useful for
students. We have removed many references to relevant works from the main
text and entered them in special bibliographic lists at the end of each chapter.
Only those references to fundamental works, which no student can afford to
overlook, have been left in the text.
Let us conclude by thanking friends and colleagues who have taken it
upon themselves to read and comment on the integrations to this edition:
Elettra Agliardi, Luigino Bruni, Luca Fiorito, Nicholas Theocarakis, Carlo
Zappia, and Luca Zarri.
vi preface to the second english edition
PREFACE TO THE FIRST EDITION
Our experience in the teaching of economics and its history has made one
thing plain to us: that keeping the two subjects separate, if it was ever justified, is certainly not today. In the face of the crisis of the theoretical
orthodoxies of the 1950s and 1960s, the flowering of innovations in recent
years, and the numerous rediscoveries of traditional wisdoms, it is no longer
an easy task to teach economic principles. We feel it necessary, therefore, to
teach economic theory by paying careful attention to its history. We have
tried to satisfy this need in our book, and this already says a great deal about
the way it has been conceived. We have endeavoured to present traditional
theories as living matter, as well as presenting modern theories as part of a
historical process and not as established truths.
On the one hand, we have tried to resist the double temptation of
rereading the past only in the light of the present and explaining the present
only by the past, or, to be more precise, to avoid searching in the traditional
theories for the seeds of the modern theories and explaining the latter as
simple accumulations of knowledge. On the other hand, we have attempted
to distance ourselves from the implicit banality of the great historiographical
alternatives, such as ‘internal’ and ‘external’ history or ‘continuism’ and
‘catastrophism’. We have also tried to avoid the dichotomy which still exists
today, and which seems to us to cause misleading simplifications, between
the ‘pure’ historians of thought, who dedicate themselves exclusively to
studying ‘facts’, and the ‘pure’ theorists, who are only interested in the
evolution of the logical structure of theories. We believe that knowledge of
the ‘environment’ in which a theory is formed is just as important as
knowledge of its logical structure, and we do not accept the view that an
analysis of the emergence of a theory must be considered as an alternative to
the study of its internal structure. This historical outline is, therefore, neither
a collection of discoveries nor a portrait gallery.
Our choice to give a fair amount of historical weight to modern developments has entailed the problem of where to end our narrative. This cannot
but be a subjective decision. We have chosen the 1970s, but we have reserved
the right to break this rule each time we felt it necessary—for example, in the
case of research work and debates which produced important results in the
1980s but which began earlier. The only precaution we have taken in these
cases has been to avoid citing names and titles, with a few exceptions, and
limiting ourselves to outlining the essential elements of the most recent
theoretical developments.
The reader accustomed to traditional history books may be surprised by
the large amount of space we have reserved for the thought of the last fifty
years—approximately half the extent of a book that still remains (all things
considered) fairly concise. If there is an imbalance of this type, however, we
believe it is that we have dedicated too little space to modern theories.
Quantitative historiographical research has shown, whichever index is used,
that scientific production has grown at an exponential rate in the last
five centuries, with the remarkable consequence that certainly more than
70 per cent of the scientists who have ever lived are living today, and perhaps
a great many more. The decision to devote less than 70 per cent of our book
to modern theory was, in fact, prudent.
Finally, we have no wish to avoid certain difficulties, or, rather,
responsibilities, connected with our endeavour to treat the present as
history. We are well aware of the danger of the attempt to be wise in the
sense advocated by William James, who believed that the art lays in knowing
what to leave out. We realize that this danger becomes greater the smaller
the distance from the material dealt with and the larger the quantity of
material about which decisions must be made; but we believe that these
responsibilities must be faced. We do not know whether we have been wise in
this sense, or to what degree, but we are convinced of one thing: even if we
have omitted many things from this book, the resulting selection has been
justified, in fact necessitated, by the importance of the material upon which
we focus.
This book is not directed to a specialist public, nor solely to a student
audience. We also hope to reach the educated person, or, rather, the person
who wishes to educate herself or himself. Specialist training is not, therefore,
necessary to understand this book; a basic knowledge of economics, however, especially the main themes of micro- and macroeconomics, would be of
help. This is true for most of the book. There are, however, sections, especially those dealing with the modern theories, in which the analytical difficulties cannot be avoided without falling into the trap of oversimplification.
In these cases, which we have tried to keep to a minimum, we have chosen to
avoid banality and to ask the reader for a little more effort.
This knowledge of the audience to whom the book is directed may help in
understanding several things about its structure; we have chosen, for
example, to avoid weighing down the narrative with footnotes, a choice that
has often restricted us, but which we hope will benefit the reader. On the
other hand the bibliographies presented at the end of each chapter do not
pretend to be complete; they contain, apart from details of works quoted
from, only a short guide to further reading.
Finally, we should like to express our gratitude to the many colleagues and
friends who have kindly and generously agreed to read and comment on the
first drafts of our book, or on parts of it. In particular we would like to
mention Duccio Cavalieri, Marco Dardi, Franco Donzelli, Riccardo Faucci,
Giorgio Gattei, Augusto Graziani, Peter Groenewegen, Vinicio Guidi, Geoff
Hodgson, Alan Kirman, Jan Kregel, Marcello Messori, Pierluigi Nuti,
Fabio Petri, Pier Luigi Porta, Maurizio Pugno, Piero Tani, and Warren
viii preface to the first edition
Young. Of course any inadequacies or mistakes in this book are our own sole
responsibility. Our thanks also go to Andrew Schuller and Anna Zaranko of
Oxford University Press for their perceptive editorial work and advice.
E. S.
S. Z.
preface to the first edition ix
This page intentionally left blank
CONTENTS
Preface to the second edition v
Preface to the first edition vii
Introduction 1
PART I FROM THE ORIGINS TO KEYNES
1. The Birth of Political Economy 19
1.1. Opening of the Modern World 19
1.1.1. The end of the Middle Ages and scholasticism 19
1.1.2. Communes, humanism and the Renaissance 22
1.1.3. The expansion of ‘Mercantile’ capitalism 27
1.1.4. The Scientific Revolution and the birth of political
economy 29
1.2. Mercantilism 32
1.2.1. Bullionism 32
1.2.2. Mercantilist commercial theories and policies 34
1.2.3. Demographic theories and policies 36
1.2.4. Monetary theories and policies 38
1.2.5. Hume’s criticism 40
1.2.6. Theories of value 41
1.3. Some Forerunners of Classical Political Economy 43
1.3.1. The premisses of a theoretical revolution 43
1.3.2. William Petty and ‘political arithmetick’ 45
1.3.3. Locke, North, and Mandeville 47
1.3.4. Boisguillebert and Cantillon 49
Relevant Works 51
Bibliography 52
2. The Laissez-Faire Revolution and Smithian Economics 54
2.1. The Laissez-Faire Revolution 54
2.1.1. The preconditions of the Industrial Revolution 54
2.1.2. Quesnay and the physiocrats 55
2.1.3. Galiani and the Italians 58
2.1.4. Hume and Steuart 63
2.2. Adam Smith 65
2.2.1. The ‘mechanical clock’ and the ‘invisible hand’ 65
2.2.2. Accumulation and the distribution of income 68
2.2.3. Value 69
2.2.4. Market and competition 72
2.2.5. Smith’s three souls 73
2.2.6. Smith as an institutionalist 77
2.3. The Smithian Orthodoxy 82
2.3.1. An era of optimism 82
2.3.2. Bentham and utilitarianism 83
2.3.3. The Smithian economists and Say 85
Relevant Works 87
Bibliography 88
3. From Ricardo to Mill 90
3.1. Ricardo and Malthus 90
3.1.1. Thirty years of crisis 90
3.1.2. The Corn Laws 91
3.1.3. The theory of rent 92
3.1.4. Profits and wages 95
3.1.5. Profits and over-production 96
3.1.6. Discussions on value 97
3.2. The Disintegration of Classical Political Economy in
the Age of Ricardo 100
3.2.1. The Ricardians, Ricardianism, and the classical tradition 100
3.2.2. The anti-Ricardian reaction 102
3.2.3. Cournot and Dupuit 104
3.2.4. Gossen and von Thu¨ nen 107
3.2.5. The Romantics and the German Historical School 109
3.3. The Theories of Economic Harmony and Mill’s Synthesis 111
3.3.1. The ‘Age of Capital’ and the theories of economic harmony 111
3.3.2. John Stuart Mill 113
3.3.3. Wages and the wages fund 115
3.3.4. Capital and the wages fund 118
3.4. English Monetary Theories and Debates in the Age of
Classical Economics 121
3.4.1. The Restriction Act 121
3.4.2. The Bank Charter Act 124
xii contents
3.4.3. Henry Thornton 127
Relevant Works 130
Bibliography 131
4. Socialist Economic Thought and Marx 133
4.1. From Utopia to Socialism 133
4.1.1. The birth of the workers’ movement 133
4.1.2. The two faces of Utopia 134
4.1.3. Saint-Simon and Fourier 135
4.2. Socialist Economic Theories 138
4.2.1. Sismondi, Proudhon, Rodbertus 138
4.2.2. Godwin and Owen 139
4.2.3. The Ricardian socialists and related theorists 140
4.3. Marx’s Economic Theory 142
4.3.1. Marx and the classical economists 142
4.3.2. Exploitation in the production process 146
4.3.3. Exploitation and value 148
4.3.4. The transformation of values into prices 151
4.3.5. Equilibrium, Say’s Law, and crises 154
4.3.6. Wages, the trade cycle, and the ‘laws of movement’ of
the capitalist economy 155
4.3.7. Monetary aspects of the cycle and the crisis 159
Relevant Works 161
Bibliography 162
5. The Triumph of Utilitarianism and the Marginalist Revolution 163
5.1. The Marginalist Revolution 163
5.1.1. The ‘climax’ of the 1870s and 1880s 163
5.1.2. The neoclassical theoretical system 165
5.1.3. Was it a real revolution? 167
5.1.4. The reasons for success 170
5.2. William Stanley Jevons 173
5.2.1. Logical calculus in economics 173
5.2.2. Wages and labour, interest and capital 176
5.2.3. English historical economics 179
5.3. Le´on Walras 180
5.3.1. Walras’s vision of the working of the economic system 180
5.3.2. General economic equilibrium 183
5.3.3. Walras and the articulation of economic science 187
contents xiii
5.4. Carl Menger 189
5.4.1. The birth of the Austrian School and the Methodenstreit 189
5.4.2. The centrality of the theory of marginal utility
in Menger 192
Relevant Works 193
Bibliography 194
6. The Construction of Neoclassical Orthodoxy 196
6.1. The Belle E´ poque 196
6.2. Marshall and the English Neoclassical Economists 198
6.2.1. Alfred Marshall 198
6.2.2. Competition and equilibrium in Marshall 200
6.2.3. Marshall’s social philosophy 202
6.2.4. Pigou and welfare economics 203
6.2.5. Wicksteed and ‘the exhaustion of the product’ 205
6.2.6. Edgeworth and bargaining negotiation 207
6.3. Neoclassical Theory in America 209
6.3.1. Clark and the marginal-productivity theory 209
6.3.2. Fisher: inter-temporal choice and the quantity
theory of money 212
6.4. Neoclassical Theory in Austria and Sweden 215
6.4.1. The Austrian School and subjectivism 215
6.4.2. The Austrian School joins the mainstream 217
6.4.3. Wicksell and the origins of the Swedish School 218
6.5. Pareto and the Italian Neoclassical Economists 223
6.5.1. From cardinal utility to ordinalism 223
6.5.2. Pareto’s criterion and the new welfare economics 226
6.5.3. Barone, Pantaleoni, and the ‘Paretaio’ 227
Relevant Works 229
Bibliography 230
7. The Years of High Theory: I 232
7.1. Problems of Economic Dynamics 232
7.1.1. Economic hard times... 232
7.1.2. Money in disequilibrium 234
7.1.3. The Stockholm School 236
7.1.4. Production and expenditure 238
xiv contents