Thư viện tri thức trực tuyến
Kho tài liệu với 50,000+ tài liệu học thuật
© 2023 Siêu thị PDF - Kho tài liệu học thuật hàng đầu Việt Nam

Advances in Spatial Science - Editorial Board Manfred M. Fischer Geoffrey J.D. Hewings Phần 6 pps
Nội dung xem thử
Mô tả chi tiết
where VA is value added and Emp is employment. In contrast to the subsequent
results, here we do not discriminate between product and process innovation and
consider any form of determinant of productivity growth.
Contrary to our expectations, no significant positive effects of innovation on
labor productivity growth are revealed in the top panel of Table 8.6. Moreover,
small manufacturing firms (between 10 and 50 employees) even experienced a
significant negative “treatment” effect of innovation on labor productivity growth
(significant at 10% only). It remains to be seen in the later specification whether this
result is robust.
One possible explanation for failure to find more conclusive results may be that
we are not capturing the relevant growth period. It may take longer than 2 years
after the initial innovation for firms to internalize all the benefits of it. To control for
this we redefined productivity growth so that we explore the growth in labor
productivity between the second and fourth year after the innovation:
growth½ ¼ ðt þ 4Þðt þ 2Þ ln VA
Emp
tþ4
ln VA
Emp
tþ2
(8.10)
The bottom panel of Table 8.6 presents estimates of the average treatment effect
of innovation on labor productivity growth between the second and fourth years
after the innovation was initially made. By changing the period of observation we
hope to capture the effects of innovation on productivity that were not apparent in
the first 2 years after the time of innovation. As before, we find that innovating firms
did not grow significantly faster (in terms of productivity) than comparable noninnovating firms. We no longer find negative impacts of innovation on productivity
growth in small manufacturing firms. Interestingly, while a non-significant impact
of innovation on productivity growth of manufacturing firms has been expected
with respect to our previous OLS results, finding non-significant results for services
firms is a little more surprising. Matching innovating and non-innovating services
firms and comparing their relative performance fails to uncover significant differences in post-treatment (i.e. post-innovation) performance between both groups.
To further disentangle the cause of this lack of evidence on the effects of
innovation on productivity growth, we opt for a more specific definition of innovation by explicitly discriminating between product and process innovations in
Table 8.7. This is based on the findings that process innovations have labor
displacement effects and are expected to result in significant productivity growth,
while, due to the demand effect, product innovations may likely cause employment
growth and, thus, may not result in significant productivity growth (Harrison et al
2005; Parisi et al 2006; Hall et al 2007).
Evidence on changes in employment after a firm has conducted some innovation, however, do not confirm these differentiated expectations (see Table B1 in
Appendix B). Notwithstanding what kind of innovation a firm has conducted, both
process and product innovating firms seem on average to decrease their employment levels. This is true for virtually all size classes with only a few exceptions.
8 Innovation and Firms’ Productivity Growth in Slovenia 187
Decreases in employment levels should therefore result in positive changes in
productivity growth in both groups of innovating firms.
Table 8.7 presents estimates of the average treatment effect separately for
process and product innovation on labor productivity growth.12 In line with the
evidence on employment changes, results for separate sets of process and product
innovating firms do not differ substantially from those presented for aggregate
innovations. Again, little evidence is found in favor of innovations positively
affecting productivity growth. As was the case before, most of the estimates are
not significantly different than zero, whereby small manufacturing firms (between
10 and 50 employees) in the case of process innovations and medium sized services
firms (between 50 and 250 employees) in the case of product innovations, are found
to experience a significant negative “treatment” effect of innovation on labor
productivity growth. These negative effects disappear when taking into account
productivity growth between the second and fourth years after the innovation
(see Tables A1 and A2 in the Appendix A).
Possibly, the reason for the insignificance of the results may be that the effects of
innovation are not adequately captured by labor productivity and that total factor
productivity should have been used instead. Additionally, our productivity proxy
may fail to control for contemporaneous growth in inputs, which may conceal the
actual productivity dynamics. In order to control for this we use a TFP measure of
productivity estimated by the Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) method. For obvious
reasons this is done for manufacturing firms only. The results shown in Table 8.8
again indicate that there is no significant relationship between innovation activity
and subsequent increases in productivity after 2 or 4 years. The only exception are
micro firms (less than 10 employees) in the period of 4 years after innovation,
where a negative relationship is found, but this result is not repeated in any other
alternative specification.
Conclusions
The paper examines the implications of endogenous growth theory on the relationship between firm productivity, innovation and productivity growth using firmlevel innovation (CIS) and accounting data for a large sample of Slovenian firms in
the period 1996–2002. Two different approaches – simple OLS after the Cre´pon–
Duguet–Mairesse (CDM) approach, and matching techniques – are used to check
the robustness of the results. We also distinguish between product and process
innovations.
12Note that we only show results for the first two years after the innovation has been introduced,
while the results for productivity growth between the second and fourth years after the innovation
was initially introduced are shown in the Appendix (Tables B1 and B2).
188 J.P. Damijan et al.
OLS estimates seem to provide some empirical support to theoretical proposition
of a positive impact of innovation on productivity growth. Both the actual innovation variables from CIS as well as probabilities to innovate estimated using the
system of the research capital equation and innovation equation indicate that
innovating firms increase their productivity at a faster rate than non-innovating
firms. Refinements of the empirical tests allowing for sectoral differences and within
sector heterogeneity, however, reveal that the above results rely mainly on the
exceptional performance of a specific group of services firms. It is shown that it is
medium sized, more (but not the most) productive firms and firms with high (but not
the highest) R&D expenditures to sales in the services sectors that are the frontrunners in innovation. They demonstrate the highest potential to increase productivity
and are capable of using innovations the most efficiently. Separate estimation results
for product and process innovations show no significant differences.
As a robustness check we use nearest neighbor matching approach in order to
match innovating and non-innovating firms with similar characteristics and then
perform average treatment tests of the impact of innovation on performance of
innovating firms as compared to the performance of non-innovating firms. Estimates arrived at by the matching techniques do not reveal any significant positive
effects of innovation on labor productivity growth, regardless of the length of the
period after the innovation was made. Results do not differ for the samples of
manufacturing versus services firms or the samples of firms classified by their size.
The results also do not show any different effects for product and process innovations. Both types of innovations bring about a reduction in employment, however,
little evidence is found in favor of innovations – be it product or process – positively
affecting productivity growth. The result is not sensitive to the use of a TFP or of a
VA/emp as a measure of productivity.
The overall conclusion is that the results of the exercise are not robust to
different econometric approaches. There are several possible reasons why our
analysis has not yielded the expected positive relationship between innovative
activity and productivity growth. In our opinion, the primary reason for these results
lies in the quality of the survey data, primarily with regard to the definition of
innovation. A simple indicator of conducting at least one (product or process)
innovation in the past 2 years may not indicate firm’s true innovativeness in a
satisfactory way. An indicator pointing out the number of innovations conducted
would be more informative. Similarly, a longer series of information about the
share of sales obtained through innovated products and services would be of
extreme importance. Secondly, we do not have the information on the exact time
of innovation, as innovative activity could happen in either of the 2 years between
surveys. Finally, it may be the case that a longer time series is required to capture
the full effects of innovation.
8 Innovation and Firms’ Productivity Growth in Slovenia 189
Appendix A
Table A1 Average treatment effects estimates of innovation on growth in VA/Emp (difference in
logs) between two and four periods after innovation (t + 4) (t + 2) [Process innovation]
Firm size Manufacturing (NACE 15–37) Services (NACE 45–90)
ATT SE No. of obs.
treat. (control)
ATT SE No. of obs.
treat. (control)
Emp 10 0.084 0.140 52 (43) 0.019 0.103 65 (47)
10 < Emp 50 0.003 0.083 114 (70) 0.062 0.133 39 (28)
50 < Emp 250 0.044 0.040 404 (194) 0.027 0.096 22 (16)
Emp > 250 0.042 0.066 318 (106) 0.027 0.136 13 (9)
Note: ***,**,* denote statistical significance at 10%, 5% and 1% level. The number of observations is given in terms of both the number of treatment and control observations (the latter is in
parentheses). SE- bootstrapped standard errors
Table A2 Average treatment effects estimates of innovation on growth in VA/Emp (difference in
logs) between two and four periods after innovation (t + 4) (t + 2) [Product innovation]
Firm size Manufacturing (NACE 15–37) Services (NACE 45–90)
ATT SE No. of obs.
treatm. (control)
ATT SE No. of obs.
treatm. (control)
Emp 10 0.084 0.140 52 (43) 0.019 0.103 65 (47)
10 < Emp 50 0.003 0.083 114 (70) 0.062 0.133 39 (28)
50 < Emp 250 0.044 0.040 404 (194) 0.027 0.096 22 (16)
Emp > 250 0.042 0.066 318 (106) 0.027 0.136 13 (9)
Note: ***,**,* denote statistical significance at 10%, 5% and 1% level. The number of observations is given in terms of both the number of treatment and control observations (the latter is in
parentheses). SE- bootstrapped standard errors
190 J.P. Damijan et al.